Question
1.Infant mortality rates in developing countries: A/ are substantially higher than in developed countries. B/ are substantially lower than in developed countries. C/ are about
1.Infant mortality rates in developing countries:
A/ are substantially higher than in developed countries.
B/ are substantially lower than in developed countries.
C/ are about the same as in developed countries.
2.Development refers to an increase in:
A/productive capacity with no change in output.
B/output brought about by a change in the production function.
C/output with no change in productive capacity.
D/output brought about by an increase in inputs.
3.In contrast to development, growth refers to an increase in:
A/output brought about by a change in the production function.
B/output brought about by an increase in inputs.
C/output with no change in productive capacity.
D/productive capacity with no change in output.
4.Countries such as China and South Korea have increased not only size of their labor force but also the quality of their labor force over time. Workers in these countries have higher levels of education and skills that promotes changes in the productivity per worker. If this is the case, these countries have experienced:
A/both development and growth.
B/growth but not development.
C/neither growth nor development.
D/development but not growth.
5.The United Nations, in its annual publication Human Development Report, computes what it calls the human development index. If the purpose of this index is to measure development rather than growth, which of the following factors is most likely to be included in it?
A/Size of the capital stock.
B/Literacy rate.
C/Number of workers in the labor force.
D/Availability of natural resources.
6.In most developing countries, an effective fiscal policy is:
A/harder to conduct because taxes are difficult to collect.
B/easier to conduct than in developed economies because there are fewer institutional checks and balances.
C/easier to conduct than in developed economies because politicians tend to be more socially-minded.
7.In 2004, Ecuador replaced its currency, the sucre, with the U.S. dollar as its official currency. The hope was that this would end record inflation running at 104 percent a year. This action prevented the government from printing excessive money to meet its budgetary needs. In terms of fiscal and monetary policy, what created the problem of inflation was that Ecuador's:
A/fiscal and monetary policy were expansionary.
B/fiscal and monetary policy were contractionary.
C/fiscal policy was expansionary but its monetary policy was contractionary.
D/fiscal policy was contractionary but its monetary policy was expansionary.
8.In 2004, Ecuador replaced its currency, the sucre, with the U.S. dollar as its official currency. The hope was that this would end record inflation running at 104 percent a year. This action prevented the government from printing excessive money to meet its budgetary needs.. As long as Ecuador maintains the U.S. dollar as its official currency, what will happen to the monetary policy of Ecuador?
A/It effectively will cease to exist.
B/It will become more powerful but less flexible.
C/It will become both more powerful and more flexible.
D/It will become less powerful but more flexible.
9.When Zimbabwe needed to finance the war against Congo, the government issued bonds and forced the Central Bank to buy those bonds in exchange of new printed Zimbabwean dollars. This action prompted a hyperinflation of almost 2,000 percent in 2007. This is an example of a lack of:
A/central bank economists running the institution.
B/a central bank independency.
C/a central bank dependency.
D/a central bank effectiveness in its monetary policy.
10.In general, the IMF provides developing countries with:
A/neither loans nor technical advice.
B/technical advice but does not provide them with loans.
C/loans and lets these countries decide how the loans will be used.
D/loans but only if the government adopts certain policies specified by the IMF in return.
11.This is from the Tax article.
Protesting against low taxes
SOMALIA is not only one of the world's poorest and least developed countries, it is also one of the most dangerous for tax collectors. By one reckoning a fifth of tax collectors in the capital, Mogadishu, were killed in 2012-14. Armed guards now accompany the remainder on their rounds. That may be an extreme case, but most poor countries struggle to raise much revenue, and therefore to pay for basic infrastructure and services.
Such difficulties will be one of the main topics of discussion at a United Nations conference in mid-July in Addis Ababa, the capital of Ethiopia, which will debate ways to finance developing countries' most urgent needs. It is a precursor to two more big powwows this year that hope to set the agenda for development for the next 15 years. At the first, in New York in September, the UN plans to adopt global targets for development, called the "sustainable development goals". At the second, in Paris in December, it hopes to agree a global scheme to combat climate change. Christine Lagarde, the head of the IMF, calls the three meetings a "once-in-a-generation opportunity for global development".
The SDGs are likely to include laudable but expensive pledges to end hunger, halt the spread of AIDS and malaria, and ensure that all children finish secondary school, among other things. The Overseas Development Institute, a British think-tank, reckons that poor countries will need $148 billion a year to meet them. But with austerity and slow growth across much of the rich world placing aid budgets under threat, poor countries will have to find other sources of finance. One of these is taxing their own citizens.
The idea of spurring development with higher taxes may seem paradoxical, since taxes are usually a drag on growth. Yet in very poor countries, which on average collect just 13% of GDP in tax compared with 34% in the rich world, the opposite is often true: public investment can "crowd in" private investment. "The amount of tax collected is a powerful measure of an economy's health," says Kaushik Basu, the chief economist of the World Bank. "Raising it allows developing countries to invest in education, health and infrastructure, and, hence, in promoting growth."
Maya Eden and Aart Kraay of the World Bank estimate that an additional dollar of public investment increases the private sort by two dollars. One target floated for the talks in Addis Ababa is to increase the tax take in low-income countries to 20%.
There are many reasons why poor countries don't collect as much tax as rich ones, the most obvious of which is that lots of their citizens are penniless. Another is that their economies are largely informal and thus beyond the reach of taxmen. The cost of tax collection in sparsely populated regions is often higher than the benefits, and around 60% of sub-Saharan Africans still live in rural areas, for example.
Yet there is plenty of room for improvement. A recent paper from the World Bank argues that some obvious reforms, such as improving tax agencies, could lead to much higher collections. Britain's Department for International Development has been sending tax administrators abroad for more than ten years to advise revenue-starved governments. One such expert, Kieran Holmes, helped to increase annual tax revenue in Rwanda by 6.5 times after automating the collection process, which reduced errors and opportunities for fraud. "Best practice for tax administration is also best practice for businesses," he says. "They like a stable and predictable environment. You don't get that when officials collect at random."
The developing world could also pick its taxes better. Property taxes, including land taxes, naturally fall on those who can afford to pay most, and are economically efficient, since they do not discourage productive activity. Yet sub-Saharan countries raise only 0.5% of GDP in this way.
Much more is possible. When four local authorities in Liberia simplified their formula for assessing property values, revenues jumped by 3-5 times. Improvements in satellite mapping are bringing down the cost of inspecting land. The Africa Research Institute points out that property taxes are typically implemented by local authorities, which also provide public services. If more power were devolved to local authorities, then better property-tax collection should go hand-in-hand with better services.
Gains would also come from reducing tax exemptions and avoidance, including by foreign investors. Katrin McGauran of SOMO, a Dutch research centre, estimates that tax treaties intended to boost Dutch investment in poor countries cost them $1 billion in revenues in 2011 alone due to the exemptions they included. The cost of multinational companies deliberately avoiding tax exceeds $200 billion a year, according to a recent IMF working paper. Angel Gurra, the secretary-general of the OECD, a club of mostly rich nations, reckons that developing countries lose three times more to tax havens than they receive in international aid each year.
The most common way multinationals avoid taxes is through "transfer pricing", in which their subsidiaries in tax havens buy goods cheaply from arms in more exacting countries, and then sell them on at a higher price, thereby shifting profits to the tax haven. The OECD is trying to combat such schemes by persuading tax authorities to require firms to disclose where they generate their profits and share the disclosures. A proposal from 137 developing-world NGOs goes further, calling for the formation of an international tax agency, although it is unlikely to prosper.
Outright tax dodging is an even bigger problem. Undeclared money transfers, false invoices and the like cost developing countries more than $990 billion in 2012, according to Global Financial Integrity, a think-tank. That figure equates to almost 4% of developing countries' GDP.
Much of the talk at the conference in Addis will be about rich countries giving more aid. In Europe, for instance, non-governmental organisations are lobbying hard for a commitment that rich countries give 0.7% of GDP in official handouts each year, despite the dismal record of official aid in ending poverty. Helping poor countries improve tax collection and limit avoidance may do far more for growth than setting lofty aid targets.
This is from the Tax article.
Per the article, the protesters are protesting to raise the money supply.
The article talks about how "public investment can 'crowd in' private investment'. The crowding in theory is opposite of the crowding out theory. Use the crowding in approach: if the government generates more tax revenue then it can borrow _________________. If it borrows _______________ then interest rates won't go _____________.
A/More; more; up
B/More; more; up
C/Less; less; down
D/Less; less; up
Step by Step Solution
There are 3 Steps involved in it
Step: 1
Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions
See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success
Step: 2
Step: 3
Ace Your Homework with AI
Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance
Get Started