Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

Demand Curve and Marginal Utility Let's start with one of the most important concepts in microeconomics: marginal analysis. For economists, the word marginal is pretty

Demand Curve and Marginal Utility

Let's start with one of the most important concepts in microeconomics: marginal analysis. For economists, the word "marginal" is pretty much the same as "additional". Marginal analysis looks at how individuals, businesses and governments make decisions. Basically, they're interested in additional benefits and additional costs.

Businesses do the same thing when they decide how many workers to hire. They compare the additional revenue that an additional worker will likely generate for their company. And to the additional cost of hiring that worker: wages and benefits. If hiring that worker brings in more marginal revenue than marginal cost, then, congratulations! Someone's got a job!

This also applies in the realm of how people feel about things. Take the development of city parks: citizens obviously get more total satisfaction from, like, four city parks than from only three. But that doesn't necessarily mean that the government should build four parks. Instead, the government looks at the additional benefit or satisfaction generated by the fourth city park and compares that to the additional cost and here, when we're talking about cost we're talking about the use of city land, and the tax money spent on building the park. If the additional benefit is higher, then they build the park. The government keeps doing this for each additional park. The benefit of the first park is higher than the additional benefit of the second park, and on and on.

Eventually, the marginal benefit of another park will be less than the marginal cost, so they stop building parks. Sure it's nice to have lots of parks, but the difference between having 200 parks and 201 parks is pretty small. This is the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility. By the way, when economists talk about consumers, the word 'utility' means 'satisfaction' or happiness people get from consuming a good, or service, or 201 parks.

So you could reword this as the Law of Decreasing Additional Satisfaction, as you consume additional amounts of anything, you'll eventually get less and less additional satisfaction. It's like how the first slice of pizza or cookie that you eat, is awesome, and the second one might be even better, but eventually, each additional one gives you less additional enjoyment.

Economists have even made up a new word to help quantify satisfaction called 'utils'. Utils are like happiness points and they are completely subjective. So one person might get 100 utils of satisfaction from the first slice of pizza and another person might only get 10 utils. So the ideas here make sense, right? But the whole numbers thing, this 'utils' idea it does seem a little contrived. People don't actually make these calculations, do they? Yeah, they do. You don't write them down or think about your happiness in terms of utils, but you do likely unconsciously use marginal analysis every day. Let's go to the Thought Bubble.

Marginal analysis can explain all sorts of human behaviour. Let's say that Stan goes to an amusement park. He's unlikely to ride the best ride in the park, the tallest rollercoaster, over and over and over, the entire day. Why? Well even if there's a one-time park admission fee and the rollercoaster is free, there's still a cost - that's how long he has to wait in line. So Stan estimates his marginal utility of riding the ride and compares that to the wait. Riding the best rollercoaster might give him the highest utility of all the rides in the park but it might not be worth waiting in a four-hour line. A smaller ride gives him less utility but if the line is super short, he'll choose that one instead. Even if there's no line for the large super-awesome rollercoaster, he probably won't ride it all day because eventually it gets old. Marginal analysis explains the behaviour of consumers like Stan, but it also explains the pricing strategies of businesses. Assume instead that the rollercoaster charges $5 for each ride. Because Stan gets less and less utility each time, he might not be willing to pay full price for the third ride The seller gets this, and figures it might be better to charge Stan less for the third ride. That's why we have deals like 'Buy two and get the third half off'. The point is we all use marginal analysis when we make decisions. Thanks, Thought Bubble. So that's marginal analysis. Armed with our new knowledge, let's go back and look at the most important model in microeconomics: supply and demand, on the runway. Let's use the market for strawberries. Remember, the price of strawberries is on the vertical axis, and quantity is on the horizontal axis.

The demand curve for strawberries is downward sloping, showing the Law of Demand. When prices are high, people don't wanna buy very many, and when prices are low, people want to buy a lot. The shape of the demand curve reflects the idea of the law of diminishing marginal utility. The first pint of strawberries you buy give you a lot of additional utility. The second one, maybe not as much. And the third pint, even less. If you eat ten pints, you're gonna get sick. So, as you consume more, you're willing to pay less and less.

This explains why the demand curve is downward sloping and why it's really just a marginal benefit curve. The supply curve is upward sloping representing the Law of supply an increase in price gives producers an incentive to produce more. It turns out that supply curves are really just marginal cost curves. It represents the additional amount of resources and energy that each additional pint of strawberries costs. This graph explains why markets tend to be so efficient with ours scarce resources. If strawberry producers produced too few strawberries, the marginal benefit of the last unit will be greater than the marginal cost. That's the market calling out for more strawberries: "Give us strawberries, please!" If they produce too much, out here, then the marginal cost would be greater than the marginal benefit, they'd be wasting resources on things that consumers don't value.

Equilibrium is efficient because the marginal benefit of the last unit consumed equals the marginal cost of that unit. The market is making the exact amount that consumers want. This is reminiscent of an example Adam Smith used. Why are diamond more expensive than water? Water is absolutely crucial for keeping us alive, while diamonds do nothing except sparkle. But the price of a bottle of life-giving water is around a buck twenty and that's when you're overpaying for water. The average one-carat diamond is well over $3,000. This is called the Diamond Water Paradox, and it can be explained with marginal analysis and the law of diminishing utility. The total utility we get from water is VERY high, but since it's so plentiful for most people, the marginal utility is really low. If you can stay hydrated, cook, take showers, wash your clothes and occasionally use your slip 'n' slide, then the additional satisfaction of yet another gallon of water is small. The result is a lower price. On the other hand, diamonds are extremely scarce because they have to be extracted from expensive, dangerous, mines. Since there are relatively few diamonds, the additional satisfaction of another one is relatively high, so people are willing to pay a higher price. If diamonds fell out of the sky like water, we wouldn't get that much additional satisfaction from them, and the price would be low. It might seem irrational that society values diamonds more than water, but using marginal analysis, it sort of makes sense. Relative scarcity does contribute to a product's value - that's partially why Action Comics number one, the first comic book with Superman recently sold for over for over 3m on eBay, but just because something is limited doesn't automatically make it valuable. There are plenty of other things that are scarce that we don't value as much as diamonds. For example, panda boogers. They're super-rare, but we don't put them on engagement rings or pay an outrageous price for one in mint condition. The point is, utility is subjective, and demand depends on the tastes and preferences of consumers. That's why there's no market for panda boogers. Hold on, Stan tells me that, because the internet, there does seem to be a market for panda boogers. But it's gotta be a small one. I think the example still holds up. Anyway, the demand also depends on the number of substitutes. For example, strawberries have plenty of substitute goods - cherries, raspberries, blueberries. When the price goes up for strawberries, consumers buy less because they'll go buy something else instead. This is a substitution effect and along with the law of diminishing marginal utility, it helped shape the demand curve

Discussion questions

1. How can the law of diminishing marginal utility explain why the demand curve for a good is downward sloping?

2. What do you think are the effects of taste and price of substitutes on the demand (curve) for a product. Explain and illustrate them graphically.

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image_2

Step: 3

blur-text-image_3

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Principles of Economics

Authors: Gregory Mankiw

7th edition

128516587X, 978-1285165875

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions