Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. ARVIND KRISHNAMURTHY AND TAFT FOSTER KEL782 Quantitative Easing in the Great Recession On October 29, 2008, the

image text in transcribed
For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. ARVIND KRISHNAMURTHY AND TAFT FOSTER KEL782 Quantitative Easing in the Great Recession On October 29, 2008, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) concluded its eighth meeting since the start of the Great Recession eleven months earlier. Continuing its recent pattern, the FOMC voted to cut its target federal funds rate by another 50 basis points, to 1%. Yet despite the lowering of this rate from 4.25% since the start of the year (see Exhibit 1), a variety of economic indicators continued to paint a grim picture. Indeed, the situation appeared to be worsening. The chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, now faced a daunting prospect. As a professor of economics at Princeton, Bernanke had studied a set of tools that a central bank could employ if its policy rate were to be constrained by the zero lower bound. Prominent among these was a tool known as \"quantitative easing,\" or QE, a policy of making large purchases of financial assets. These purchases increased the quantity of money in the economy, hence the name quantitative easing. In his academic writings, Bernanke had advocated QE as a policy for Japan, where since the late 1990s the Bank of Japan (BoJ) had reduced its short-term interest rate to near zero.1 With the federal funds rate at 1%, the Federal Reserve likely would soon find itself in the same position as the BoJ, namely at the zero lower bound. Bernanke would get a chance to put his academic theories into practice. The Great Recession and Financial Crisis What would later be called the Great Recession began officially in December 2007 as a typical economic downturn associated with a spike in oil prices and a decline in home prices, but it quickly became a severe recession due to links between the housing and financial markets. As home prices across the United States and other countries fell in 2006 and 2007, foreclosure rates began to rise; this in turn rendered almost worthless many previously AAA-rated mortgagebacked securities (MBS) that derived their value from pools of mortgages (see Exhibit 2 and Exhibit 3). In turn, uncertainty about which financial institutions held worthless MBSand which financial institutions insured the losses of those that didcaused what amounted to bank runs on several large financial institutions. 1 See Ben Bernanke, \"Japanese Monetary Policy: A Case of Self-Induced Paralysis?\" in Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam Simon Posen, eds., Japan's Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2000). 2014 by the Kellogg School of Management at Northwestern University. This case was developed with support from the June 2010 graduates of the Executive MBA Program (EMP-78). This case was prepared by Professor Arvind Krishnamurthy and Taft Foster '13. The authors would like to thank Jonathan Palm Cohen for his research assistance. Cases are developed solely as the basis for class discussion. Cases are not intended to serve as endorsements, sources of primary data, or illustrations of effective or ineffective management. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 800-545-7685 (or 617-783-7600 outside the United States or Canada) or e-mail custserv@hbsp.harvard.edu. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any meanselectronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the permission of Kellogg Case Publishing. This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Early notable victims included Countrywide Financial, which reached a deal in January 2008 to be purchased by Bank of America, and Northern Rock, which was nationalized by the British government in February 2008. Both were heavily involved in mortgage lending and unable to obtain financing through credit markets. Then, on March 16, 2008, the FOMC held an emergency meeting in response to the imminent collapse of Bear Stearns, at that time the fifth largest investment bank in the United States. During that meeting, the Federal Reserve pledged financing for J.P. Morgan to purchase Bear Stearns at $2 per share, less than 7% of Bear Stearns's market value two days earlier. Six months later, another large investment bank, Lehman Brothers, faced a similar crisis. This time, however, the Federal Reserve was unable or unwilling to provide a bailout, and no buyer could be found. As a result, Lehman Brothers, the fourth largest U.S. investment bank at the time, filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection on September 15, 2008. On the day of Lehman's bankruptcy filing, the Dow Jones Industrial Average plummeted 500 points (-4.4%), its largest decline since the attacks of September 11, 2001. Lehman's downfall created widespread panic in financial markets, as investors scrambled to move their funds out of other potentially at-risk institutions and investments. The multinational insurance giant AIG suffered a liquidity crisis the day after Lehman's bankruptcy filing. This time, however, the Federal Reserve stepped in to prevent the collapse of AIG by providing a secured credit facility of up to $85 billion. This was followed a week later by the federal takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) that securitized mortgages in the form of MBS. Exhibit 4 shows the magnitude of financial institution write-downs throughout this period. By the time the FOMC met on October 29, the Dow Jones had dropped more than 2,300 points, or 20.6%, since Lehman's bankruptcy. Meanwhile, the turmoil in the financial sector was also being felt in the real economy. According to the Federal Reserve's October 2008 Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey, credit standards were tightening sharply (see Exhibit 5). Real GDP fell 3.7% during the third quarter of 2008 and the unemployment rate, which was on a sharp upward trajectory, reached 6.5% in October, up from 5% at the start of the recession (see Exhibit 6). Quantitative Easing As the economic situation continued to deteriorate following the October 29 FOMC meeting, it became clear that the Federal Reserve would soon be forced to lower its target rate further. With the target rate already at 1%, however, the Federal Reserve did not have much room for further easing. Monetary policy would soon be constrained by the zero lower bound. The Zero Lower Bound One way to look at the zero lower bound is through the lens of the Taylor rule. Named after its creator, Stanford economist John Taylor, this mathematical formula indicates how much a central bank should adjust its policy rate in response to changes in inflation, output, or unemployment. More specifically, Taylor proposed the following equation: 2 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Applying this equation to the United States, represents the federal funds rate, is the is the inflation rate, is the Federal Reserve's target inflation equilibrium real interest rate, rate, is the logarithm of real GDP, and is the logarithm of potential output. The coefficients and tell the Federal Reserve how much to adjust the federal funds rate in response to deviations in the inflation rate from its target and to deviations in real GDP from potential output.2 From 1988 to 2007, under first Alan Greenspan and then Ben Bernanke, the Federal Reserve had set the federal funds rate in a manner that could be described by a modified Taylor rule (see Exhibit 1). The main difference between Taylor's rule and actual Federal Reserve policy was that equal to oneTaylor proposed, in a paper published in 1993, that the Federal Reserve choose equal to one-half, whereas the Federal Reserve appeared to choose to be closer to half and one.3 Beginning in late 2008, the Federal Reserve's modified Taylor rule began to recommend a negative federal funds rate, something that was impossible to implement. This constraint on the federal funds rate is a consequence of the fact that investors can always earn at least a 0% nominal return by holding cash. As a result, banks will almost never be willing to lend reserves at a rate below 0%, that is, to pay to lend reserves. So, according to the modified Taylor rule, by late 2008, Federal Reserve policy was constrained by the zero lower bound. Although new to the Federal Reserve, the zero lower bound was familiar territory for Japan's central bank, the BoJ. In 1995 the BoJ had dropped its target rate below 1% in an attempt to combat deflation and a stagnant economy. This rate remained close to zero for several years, but Japan's Lost Decade continued unabated. So in 2001, under pressure to do something more to stimulate the Japanese economy, the BoJ became the world's first central bank to try quantitative easing. Among those calling for increased use of quantitative easing in Japan at that time was Ben Bernanke, then a Princeton economics professor.4 Seven years later, Bernanke had the opportunity to put his theories to the test in the United States. QE1 On November 25, 2008, the Federal Reserve issued a press release announcing plans to purchase up to $600 billion in financial assets in what would later be referred to as QE1. Of these funds, $500 billion would be used to purchase MBS backed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Ginnie Mae. The remaining $100 billion would go to purchase direct obligations (i.e., plain vanilla bonds rather than MBS) of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks. Over the next four months, the Federal Reserve made four more announcements regarding quantitative easing. On December 1, Bernanke gave a speech in which he described \"several 2 The Taylor rule is sometimes written in terms of unemployment gaps rather than GDP gaps, appealing to Okun's law relating GDP to gap deviations to unemployment deviations. In this case, the last term in the Taylor rule is modified from , where is the unemployment rate and is the natural rate of unemployment. 3 See John B. Taylor, \"Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,\" Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1993): 195-214, and John B. Taylor, \"A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,\" in Monetary Policy Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999), pp. 319-41. 4 See Ben Bernanke, \"Japanese Monetary Policy: A Case of Self-Induced Paralysis?\" in Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam Simon Posen, eds., Japan's Financial Crisis and Its Parallels to U.S. Experience (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2000). KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 3 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 means by which the Fed could influence financial conditions through the use of its balance sheet,\" including purchases of \"longer-term Treasury or agency securities on the open market in substantial quantities.\"5 Then, on December 16, the FOMC lowered its target federal funds rate to 0%-0.25%, essentially hitting the zero lower bound. The press release for this meeting also stated that the Federal Reserve stood \"ready to expand its purchases of agency debt and mortgagebacked securities as conditions warrant\" and was \"also evaluating the potential benefits of purchasing longer-term Treasury securities.\"6 Similar comments were made after the subsequent FOMC meeting held on January 28.7 Finally, on March 18, the Federal Reserve expanded QE1 to include $1.25 trillion in MBS purchases and $300 billion in long-term Treasury purchases. Although it is impossible to fully identify the effects of QE1 on the economy, some insight about its effects can be obtained using an event study methodology.8 With this approach, key variables are observed shortly before and after each of the five announcements described above. To the degree that these announcements represented the dominant news affecting the market on their respective dates, changes in certain variables around the announcements can shed light on the channels through which QE1 operated, as well as its overall impact. Intraday movements in 10-year Treasury yields and trading volume for each of the event dates provide evidence that the five announcements were indeed the major piece of news on their respective dates (see Exhibit 7). Further evidence for the effects of QE1 can be found in Table 1 below, which displays the two-day changes in the yields of several securities summed across the five event dates. Table 2 contains this same information for federal funds futures at various maturities; the average yield curve before and after the five announcements provide additional evidence (see Exhibit 8). Table 1: Changes in Yields (in Basis Points) on Select Securities QE1 QE2 5-year Treasuries -74 -17 10-year Treasuries -107 -18 Agency MBS (10-year duration) -107 -12 -81 -7 Baa Corporate Yield Credit Default Swap 10-year TIPS a a -40 2 -187 -25 The credit default swap yield in this table corresponds to an index of Baa corporates. Table 2: Changes in Yields (in Basis Points) on Federal Funds Futures by Maturity QE1 QE2 3rd month -28 0 6th month -27 -1 12th month -33 -4 24th month -40 -11 5 Ben S. Bernanke, \"Federal Reserve Policies in the Financial Crisis,\" speech at the Greater Austin Chamber of Commerce, Austin, Texas, December 1, 2008, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/speech/bernanke20081201a.htm. 6 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, December 16, 2008, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/ press/monetary/20081216b.htm. 7 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, January 28, 2009, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/ press/monetary/20090128a.htm. 8 See Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,\" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2011. 4 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING QE1 was executed over a period of sixteen months and concluded when the last of its purchases were made during March 2010. By that time, the U.S. economy was no longer in free fall, but the unemployment rate was 9.9% and the recovery appeared to be proceeding at a slow pace. Meanwhile, dark clouds were forming over Europe, which was showing early signs of a sovereign debt crisis. After months of sluggish recovery and talk of a \"double-dip recession,\" Wall Street began to speculate about QE2. QE2 The first official hint of QE2 came on August 10, 2010, when the FOMC announced its plan to \"keep constant the Federal Reserve's holdings of securities at their current level by reinvesting principal payments from agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in longer-term Treasury securities.\"9 Prior to this announcement, markets had expected the Federal Reserve to gradually reduce its balance sheet. The announcement indicated a shift toward long-term Treasuries and away from MBS, which had been the focus of QE1. The next FOMC announcement on September 21 reaffirmed this position and added that the committee was \"prepared to provide additional accommodation if needed to support the economic recovery.\"10 This language was interpreted by many market participants as signaling a new round of asset purchases by the Federal Reserve. For example, Goldman Sachs economists forecasted that the Federal Reserve would purchase up to $1 trillion of Treasuries.11 As a result of these widespread expectations, markets were underwhelmed when, on November 3, the FOMC finally announced its plan to purchase $600 billion in long-term Treasuries. Applying the event study approach to QE2, there are three possible dates to work with, but because the November 3 announcement was largely priced into the market beforehand, only the August 10 and September 21 announcements are included in the data provided here. Intraday movements in 10-year Treasury yields and trading volumes provide evidence that the QE2 announcements were the major news event on their respective release dates (see Exhibit 9). As with QE1, further evidence can be found in the changes in security yields and the yields on federal funds futures (see Tables 1 and 2), and the average yield curve before and after the announcements provide additional evidence (see Exhibit 10). QE3 On September 13, 2012, the Federal Reserve launched QE3. It was announced that the Federal Reserve would purchase MBS at a pace of $40 billion per month, and it would purchase longer-term Treasury securities at a pace of $45 billion per month. The Treasury purchases were for the most part expected, but the announcement of MBS purchases took the market by surprise. It indicated a shift back toward MBS, unlike the exclusive focus on Treasury securities in QE2. Of further surprise was the Federal Reserve's indication that purchases would continue until the 9 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, August 10, 2010, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/press/ monetary/20100810a.htm. 10 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 21, 2010, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/ press/monetary/20100921a.htm. 11 \"FOMC Rate DecisionFed Signals Willingness to Ease Further if Growth or Inflation Continue to Disappoint,\" Goldman Sachs Newsletter, September 21, 2010. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 5 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 labor market improved, within the context of price stability. The press release stated, \"If the outlook for the labor market does not improve substantially, the Committee will continue its purchases of agency mortgage-backed securities, undertake additional asset purchases, and employ its other policy tools as appropriate until such improvement is achieved in a context of price stability.\"12 The open-ended nature of this purchase commitment led some commentators to dub QE3 as \"QE infinity.\"13 Table 3: Changes in Yields (in Basis Points) on Select Securities QE3 5-year Treasuries -6 10-year Treasuries -3 Agency MBS (10-year duration) -15 Baa Corporate Yield Credit Default Swap 10-year TIPS a 0 a 0 -11 The credit default swap yield in this table corresponds to an investment grade index. Table 4: Changes in Yields (in Basis Points) on Federal Funds Futures by Maturity QE3 3rd month 0 6th month 0 12th month 0 24th month -3 The event study for QE3 involves only one clear-cut surprise date, the announcement date of September 13, 2012. Table 3 and Table 4 provide data on the one-day change in asset prices across the event date.14 The QE Debate Although Bernanke had been a longtime proponent of quantitative easing and the majority of FOMC members agreed that QE1, QE2, and QE3 were merited, committee members held a wide range of views regarding the policy. Much of the debate surrounded the potential costs and benefits of the Federal Reserve's actions. 12 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, press release, September 13, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/ press/monetary/20120913a.htm. 13 Sam Jones, \"Hedge Fund Sceptics Warn on 'QE Infinity,'\" Financial Times, September 25, 2012. 14 See Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Ins and Outs of Large Scale Asset Purchases,\" Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium on the Global Dimensions of Unconventional Monetary Policy, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 2013. 6 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Potential Benefits of QE Janet Yellen, former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and vice chairwoman of the Federal Reserve, was a vocal supporter of quantitative easing. In a January 2011 speech defending the Federal Reserve's decision to proceed with QE2, she described the policy's potential benefits: Turning now to the macroeconomic effects of the Federal Reserve's securities purchases, there are several distinct channels through which these purchases tend to influence aggregate demand, including a reduced cost of credit to consumers and businesses, a rise in asset prices that boosts household wealth and spending, and a moderate change in the foreign exchange value of the dollar that provides support to net exports.15 She also cited the results of the Federal Reserve's forecasting model, which predicted that by 2012, \"the full program of securities purchases will have raised private payroll employment by about 3 million jobs.\"16 In an October 2010 speech, William Dudley, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and another of the FOMC's so-called inflation doves,17 emphasized the effects of quantitative easing through the mortgage-rate and business-lending channels: Lower long-term rates would make housing more affordable and support consumption by enabling households to refinance their mortgages at lower rates. This would increase the amount of income left over for other spending. Of course, this channel can be made more powerful to the extent that further progress can be made in efficient mortgage debt restructurings that allow households with negative equity in their homes to take advantage of the drop in mortgage rates. In addition, lower long-term rates would reduce the cost of capital for businesses, thereby fostering higher levels of capital spending for any given economic outlook.18 In addition to the channels emphasized in these speeches, Chairman Bernanke also described the signaling channel of quantitative easing: Large-scale asset purchases . . . can signal that the central bank intends to pursue a persistently more accommodative policy stance than previously thought, thereby lowering 15 Janet L. Yellen, \"The Federal Reserve's Asset Purchase Program,\" speech at the The Brimmer Policy Forum, Allied Social Science Associations Annual Meeting, Denver, Colorado, January 8, 2011, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/speech/ yellen20110108a.htm. 16 Ibid. 17 The Federal Reserve has a dual mandate to create high employment and keep inflation low. The term \"dove\" is used to indicate a policymaker who places a greater weight on high employment in this dual mandate, while the term \"hawk\" is used to indicate a policymaker who places a greater weight on inflation. 18 William C. Dudley, \"The Outlook, Policy Choices and Our Mandate,\" speech at the Society of American Business Editors and Writers Fall Conference, City University of New York, Graduate School of Journalism, New York City, October 1, 2010, http://www.newyorkfed.orgewsevents/speeches/2010/dud101001.html. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 7 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 investors' expectations for the future path of the federal funds rate and putting additional downward pressure on long-term interest rates, particularly in real terms.19 Furthermore, Bernanke pointed out that during periods of financial crisis like that of late 2008, \"asset purchases may also improve the functioning of financial markets, thereby easing credit conditions in some sectors.\"20 Potential Costs of QE In a November 2010 speech, Richard Fisher, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas and one of the FOMC's so-called inflation hawks, described the doubts he had about QE2: I could not state with conviction that purchasing another several hundred billion dollars of Treasurieson top of the amount we were already committed to buy in order to compensate for the run-off in our $1.25 trillion portfolio of mortgage-backed securities would lead to job creation and final-demand-spurring behavior. But I could envision such action would lead to a declining dollar, encourage further speculation, provoke commodity hoarding, accelerate the transfer of wealth from the deliberate saver and the unfortunate, and possibly place at risk the stature and independence of the Fed.21 In February 2013, Federal Reserve Governor Jeremy Stein gave a speech on what he saw as overheating in the credit markets. Exhibit 11 and Exhibit 12, which are figures referred to in Stein's speech, show that inflows into high-yield mutual funds, high-yield exchange traded funds (ETFs), and real-estate investment trusts (REITs) had surged from 2010 onward. Commenting on these market developments, Stein noted: . . . a prolonged period of low interest rates, of the sort we are experiencing today, can create incentives for agents to take on greater duration or credit risks, or to employ additional financial leverage, in an effort to \"reach for yield.\" An insurance company that has offered guaranteed minimum rates of return on some of its products might find its solvency threatened by a long stretch of low rates and feel compelled to take on added risk. A similar logic applies to a bank whose net interest margins are under pressure because low rates erode the profitability of its deposit-taking franchise . . .22 In a December 2010 speech, Charles Plosser, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, expressed concerns about the Federal Reserve's ability to reduce its balance sheet without stoking inflation: While the high level of excess reserves is not inflationary now, as the economic recovery strengthens, the Fed must be able to remove or isolate these reserves to keep them from 19 Ben S. Bernanke, \"Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis,\" speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 31, 2012, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm. 20 Ibid. 21 Richard W. Fisher, remarks before the Association for Financial Professionals, San Antonio, Texas, November 8, 2010, http://dallasfed.orgews/speeches/fisher/2010/fs101108.cfm. 22 Jeremy C. Stein, \"Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and Policy Responses,\" speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri, February 7, 2013, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/speech/stein20130207a.htm. 8 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING becoming what I have called the kindling that could fuel excessive inflation. In other words, if banks began to put the reserves to use in the same manner as they did before the crisis, money in circulation would increase sharply. We do not know when that will happen or how long it will take for the banking system to make the adjustment. To address this looming challenge, the Fed is developing and testing tools to help us prevent such a rapid explosion in money. But, of course, we won't know for certain how effective these new tools are until we need to use them in our exit strategy.23 Exhibit 13 plots the monetary base (M0), which includes bank reserves as well as currency in circulation. Plosser's concern regarding the high level of bank reserves is reflected in the rapid growth of M0. As Plosser notes, broader measures of money in circulation such as M2 (see Exhibit 11) have not kept pace with M0, indicating that banks have not put the reserves to use. Exhibit 14 plots the yields on 10-year nominal Treasury bonds and 10-year Treasury inflation indexed bonds (TIPS). The difference between the yields in these series can be used to measure long-term inflation expectations. Plosser also pointed out the fact that \"the Federal Reserve also faces interest rate risk by purchasing these long-term government bonds. If rates go up and the Fed were forced to sell the bonds in order to prevent inflation, the Fed would take a loss.\"24 In a March 2009 speech, Jeffrey Lacker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, described his view that recent Federal Reserve actions put the central bank's political independence at risk: Government lending, whether by the Fed or by the Treasury, fundamentally represents fiscal policy in the sense that it channels taxpayer funds to private sector entities. The presumption ought to be that such lending is subject to the checks and balances of the appropriations process laid out in the Constitution. Using the Fed's balance sheet is at times the path of least resistance, because it allows government lending to circumvent the Congressional approval process. This risks entangling the Fed in attempts to influence credit allocation, thereby exposing monetary policy to political pressures.25 Table 5: Holdings of Agency MBS and US Treasury Debt, by Holder ($ in billions) Agency MBS Fed Treasury (1-5 yr) Non-Fed Fed Non-Fed Treasury (>5 yr) Fed Non-Fed 30-Jun-08 0 4,756 173 1,389 183 1,275 30-Jun-12 947 4,656 516 3,710 1,092 2,335 30-Jun-13 1,208 4,547 552 4,125 1,382 2,392 Source: Federal Reserve, U.S. Treasury, SIFMA. 23 Charles I. Plosser, \"Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy,\" speech at the 32nd Annual Economic Seminar, Rochester, New York, December 2, 2010, http://www.philadelphiafed.org/publications/speeches/plosser/2010/12-02-10_university-of-rochester.cfm. 24 Ibid. 25 Jeffrey M. Lacker, \"Government Lending and Monetary Policy,\" speech at the 2009 National Association for Business Economics Economic Policy Conference, Alexandria, Virginia, March 2, 2009, http://www.richmondfed.org/press_room/speeches/ president_jeff_lacker/2009/lacker_speech_20090302.cfm. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 9 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 As of the summer of 2013, the Federal Reserve's actions in the MBS and Treasury market were substantial relative to the size of these markets. Table 5 provides data on the Federal Reserve and private sector's (i.e., non-Fed) holdings of long maturity U.S. Treasury debt, broken down into Treasury bonds with one- to five-year maturity and bonds with greater than five-year maturity. The table also provides data on the holdings of Agency MBS. As the table shows, the Federal Reserve was substantially invested in these markets, and these numbers begged the question of how much involvement was too much. 10 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Definitions CREDIT DEFAULT SWAPS A credit default swap (CDS) is a financial derivative contract between two parties. The seller of the CDS agrees to compensate the buyer in the event that a third party defaults on a loan or debt obligation. In return, the buyer makes a series of payments to the seller. For a buyer who is also the holder of the specified loan, a CDS provides insurance against default; however, buyers of CDS contracts are not required to hold the loan in question. A CDS in which the buyer has no direct insurable interest is referred to as a \"naked\" CDS. Given their insurance value, CDS yields are often used as a measure of credit risk. For example, let us suppose that the CDS price for five years of protection against default on the senior debt of Bank A trades at 1%. This means that to insure against default on $1,000 face value of senior debt of Bank A, the buyer of the CDS pays an insurance premium of 1% $1,000 = $10 annually. Suppose an investor purchases $1,000 of the senior debt of Bank A at par and offering a yield of 5%. Then, if the investor further purchases the CDS against the default on this debt, the investor will effectively own a riskless bond whose return is equal to 4% (i.e., 5% - 1%). Thus, the 1% CDS price measures the credit or default risk on this bond. FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES Federal funds futures are standardized, exchange-traded derivative contracts. In order to describe this contract, let denote the average value of the daily effective federal funds rate over some future month, and let denote the current federal funds futures rate for contracts settled at the end of that month. The buyer of a federal funds futures contract that matures at the end of the month in question must compensate the seller if it turns out that , and vice versa if . Because federal funds futures represent bets on the value of the federal funds rate at different time horizons, they are often used to gauge market expectations about future Federal Reserve policy. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 11 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 1: Actual Federal Funds Rate and Taylor Rules, 1988-2014 Federal Funds Rate Taylor (1993) Rule Modified Taylor Rule 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data, Congressional Budget Office. Note: The Taylor rules in this chart are based on: i r u u where the output term has been replaced with u u , following footnote 2 and an Okun's law estimate of the relationship between the output gap and unemployment of one-half. The original rule proposed by John Taylor in Taylor (1993) sets equal to one-half and equal to one. The modified Taylor rule sets equal to one-half and equal to two. The data for the chart is based on unemployment and core CPI inflation. The inflation target ( ) is assumed to be 2%; the natural rate of interest (r ) is assumed to be 2%; and the natural rate of unemployment (u ) is based on the Congressional Budget Office's quarterly estimates. 12 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 2: S&P/Case-Shiller Ten-City Index of Home Prices, 2000-2013 250 200 150 100 50 0 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data Note: Indexed to 100 in 2000. Exhibit 3: Percentage of Homeowners with Negative Equity 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 Sources: FDIC, Equifax, Moody's Analytics. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 13 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 4: U.S. Financial Institutions (Banks/Brokers, Insurance, Monolines) Writedowns and Capital Raised (billions of dollars) 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 Cumulative Writedowns Cumulative Capital Raised Source: Bloomberg. 14 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 5: Lending Standards for Mortgage and Consumer Loans, 2000-2014 Net Percentage of Domestic Banks Tightening Standards on Consumer Loans, Credit Cards 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 10% 20% 30% 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data. Net Percentage of Domestic Banks Tightening Standards for Prime Mortgage Loans Net Percentage of Domestic Banks Tightening Standards for Nontraditional Mortgage Loans 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 20% 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 15 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 6: U.S. Macroeconomic Data Unemployment rate (U3) Comprehensive unemployment (U6) 20% 18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data. Real GDP CBO estimated Real Potential GDP 17,000 16,000 Billions of $ 15,000 14,000 13,000 12,000 11,000 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data, Congressional Budget Office. 16 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 7: 10-Year Treasury Yields and Trading Volumes on the Five QE1 Event Dates Source: Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,\" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2011. Note: The x-axis gives time of day, with the vertical lines marking the event time corresponding to a QE announcement. The top panel graphs 10-year Treasury yields over the trading day, while the bottom panel graphs trading volume in the 10-year Treasury bond over the trading day. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 17 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 8: Pre- and Post-QE1 Announcement Average Yield Curve from Federal Funds Futures Source: Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,\" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2011. 18 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 9: 10-Year Treasury Yields and Trading Volumes on the Two QE2 Event Dates Source: Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,\" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2011. Note: The x-axis gives time of day, with the vertical lines marking the event time corresponding to a QE announcement. The top panel graphs 10-year Treasury yields over the trading day, while the bottom panel graphs trading volume in the 10-year Treasury bond over the trading day. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 19 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 10: Pre- and Post-QE2 Announcement Average Yield Curve from Federal Funds Futures Source: Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, \"The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,\" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2011. 20 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 11: Credit Market Inflows, 2000-2012 Source: Jeremy C. Stein, \"Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and Policy Responses,\" speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri, February 7, 2013, http://www.federalreserve.govewsevents/speech/stein20130207a.htm, from Morningstar. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 21 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. QUANTITATIVE EASING KEL782 Exhibit 12: Mortgage REIT Assets, 2000-2013 (billions of dollars) 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Source: Federal Reserve Financial Accounts of the United States. Exhibit 13: Money Supply Measures, 2000-2014 M2 (left axis) M0 (right axis) 12,000 4,000 3,500 10,000 2,500 6,000 2,000 1,500 4,000 Billions of dollars Billions of dollars 3,000 8,000 1,000 2,000 0 2000 500 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 0 2014 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data. 22 KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017. For the exclusive use of X. Ye, 2017. KEL782 QUANTITATIVE EASING Exhibit 14: Yields on Nominal Treasury Bonds and Inflation Protected Treasury Bonds, 2003-2014 10Year Treasury, Constant Maturity 10Year TIPS, Constant Maturity 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 2.00 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data. KELLOGG SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT 23 This document is authorized for use only by Xinyang Ye in ECO 9713 Spring 2017 taught by Rhonda Halpern, CUNY - Baruch College from February 2017 to August 2017

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image

Step: 3

blur-text-image

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Econometric Evaluation Of Socio-Economic Programs Theory And Applications

Authors: Giovanni Cerulli

1st Edition

3662464055, 9783662464052

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions

Question

Could this be a case of a classically conditioned phobia?

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

What are the APPROACHES TO HRM?

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

What do you mean by dual mode operation?

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

Explain the difference between `==` and `===` in JavaScript.

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

What other blunt questions do you think would be appropriate?

Answered: 1 week ago