Question
Fuelling discontent23 How much should petrol be taxed? The tax on petrol varies widely around the developed world. America's gasoline tax is currently about 40
Fuelling discontent23
How much should petrol be taxed?
The tax on petrol varies widely around the developed
world. America's gasoline tax is currently about 40
cents an American gallon, equivalent to 7 pence a
litre. Many Americans are calling for it to be cut, as the
summer increase in prices begins to make itself felt,
and reflecting a more general alarm about the
country's 'energy crisis'. In Canada the tax is half as
big again as in America; in Australia it is more than
double. In Japan and most of Europe, the specific tax
on petrol is around five times higher than in America,
standing at the equivalent of some 35 pence a litre. At
the upper extreme is Britain, where fuel duty (paid in
addition to value-added tax) has risen in recent years
to a punitive rate of just under 50 pence a litre, seven
times the American levy.
You would expect well-designed petrol taxes to
vary from country to country, according to national
circumstances - but not, on the face of it, by a factor
of seven. In America it is taken for granted that
Europe's petrol taxes, let alone Britain's, are insanely
high, and presumably something to do with
socialism. In Britain, on the other hand, it is taken for
granted that America's gas tax is insanely low, part of
a broader scheme to wreck the planet. Protests in
Britain last year showed that petrol tax had finally
been raised all the way up to its political ceiling - but
nobody expects or even calls for the tax to be cut to
the American level.
America and Britain may both be wrong about the
gas tax, but it seems unlikely that they can both be
right. So how heavily should petrol be taxed? A paper
by Ian Parry of Resources for the Future, an
environmental think-tank in Washington, DC, looks at
the arguments.
The most plausible justification for taxing petrol
more highly than other goods is that using the stuff
harms the environment and adds to the costs of
traffic congestion. This is indeed how Britain's
government defends its policy. But the fact that
burning petrol creates these 'negative externalities'
does not imply, as many seem to think, that no tax on
petrol could ever be too high. Economics is precise
about the tax that should, in principle, be set to deal
with negative externalities: the tax on a litre of fuel
should be equal to the harm caused by using a litre of
fuel. If the tax is more than that, its costs (which
include the inconvenience inflicted on people who
would rather have used their cars) will exceed its
benefits (including any reduction in congestion and
pollution).
The pollution costs of using petrol are of two main
kinds: damage to health from breathing in emissions
such as carbon monoxide and assorted particulates,
and broader damage to the environment through the
contribution that burning petrol makes to global
warming. Reviewing the literature, Mr Parry notes
that most recent studies estimate the health costs of
burning petrol at around 10 pence a litre or less. The
harm caused by petrol's contribution to global
warming is, for the time being, much more
speculative. Recent high-damage scenarios,
however, put an upper limit on the cost at about
$100 per ton of carbon, equivalent to 5 pence a litre
of petrol. Adding these together, you come to an
optimal petrol tax of no more than 15 pence a litre.
JAMMED
High petrol taxes also help to reduce traffic
congestion. However, they are badly designed for
that purpose. Curbing the number of car journeys is
only one way to reduce congestion. Others include
persuading people either to drive outside peak hours
or to use routes that carry less traffic. High petrol taxes
fail to exploit those additional channels. As a result,
Mr Parry finds, the net benefits of a road-specific
peak-period fee (the gain of less congestion minus
the cost of disrupted travel) would be about three
times bigger than a petrol-tax increase calculated to
curb congestion by the same amount. Still, if politics
or technology rules out congestion-based roadpricing,
a second-best case can be made for raising
the petrol tax instead. According to Mr Parry,
congestion costs in Britain might then justify an
additional 10 pence a litre in tax.
This brings you to a total petrol tax of around 25
pence a litre. The pre-tax price of petrol is currently
about 20 pence a litre, so this upper-bound estimate
of the optimal tax represents a tax rate of well over
100% - a 'high tax', to be sure. Yet Britain's current
rate is roughly double this. On the same basis, of
course, America's rate is far too low (even a lower
bound for the optimal rate would be a lot higher than
7 pence a litre).
512 STRATEGY ANALYSIS
3. Managers may also anticipate consumer reactions to externalities and
take the necessary actions. Examples of situations where this was not done are
the Exxon Valdez oil spill and the Union Carbide disaster in India. In both cases
consumers saw these firms as uncaring about the externalities that they had
caused and much goodwill was lost, and ultimately customers also.
The final case study in the chapter involves the evaluation of the optimal
level of tax for petrol, based on the externalities involved. In practice, products
are often taxed for reasons other than externalities: they are convenient
sources of revenue. This applies to cigarettes and alcohol in particular. More
recently, speed cameras have come into use to target drivers for fines, which
essentially amount to a tax. Again, the introduction of cameras has largely
been for revenue reasons rather than for safety. All these cases tend to involve
inelastic demand; otherwise they would not be so attractive to governments as
a source of revenue. However, in their desire to obtain such revenue, governments
should not ignore the distorting effects on the market of the taxes
involved, even in the case of speeding fines.
12.5 Imperfect information
As seen earlier, there are two main aspects to this, incomplete information and
asymmetric information. These are not mutually exclusive categories, but in
the first case the main concern of the government is consumers' lack of
information, whereas in the second it is the fact that one party to a transaction
has more information pertaining to the transaction than the other.
Britain's rate, judged according to the
environmental and congestion arguments, looks way
too high - but plainly the British government has
another reason for taxing petrol so heavily. It needs
the money to finance its plans for public spending.
Politically, raising money through the tax on petrol,
protests notwithstanding, has proved far easier than
it would have been to collect the cash through
increases in income tax or in the broadly based valueadded
tax - or, for that matter, through congestionbased
road-pricing (always dismissed as 'politically
impossible').
This seems odd. Supposing that actual and
projected public spending justified higher taxation,
Mr Parry's analysis strongly suggests that the country
would have been better off paying for it through
income taxes than through a punitive petrol tax. And
the petrol tax is not only wasteful in economic terms,
if Mr Parry is right; it is also regressive in its
distributional effects, increasing the cost of living for
poor car-owning households much more than for
their richer counterparts.
At last, Britain has found the political ceiling for the
petrol tax. What is remarkable is just how high it
proved to be.
Questions
1 What are the economic reasons for fuel taxes being
different in different countries?
2 What additional factors are relevant in explaining
why fuel taxes in the UK are seven times the level in
the USA?
3 Why are fuel taxes an inefficient way of reducing
traffic congestion?
4 Given that fuel taxes are higher in the UK than
the rest of Europe, what implications does this
have for UK firms competing with European
ones?
Step by Step Solution
There are 3 Steps involved in it
Step: 1
Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions
See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success
Step: 2
Step: 3
Ace Your Homework with AI
Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance
Get Started