Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

Having reviewed the opening lecture and this week's reading inHBR's OnStrategy Vol. 2,think about all the changes we've experience in the global marketplace in just

Having reviewed the opening lecture and this week's reading inHBR's OnStrategy Vol. 2,think about all the changes we've experience in the global marketplace in just the last 3 months.Where are you seeing examples ofpipelines, platforms and new rules being put into place?

Instructions:

  • Use specific examples in your answer and emphasize the "good news" stories: organizations that you admire, or examplesthat show how organizations can adapt to disruption and do so with great success at leveraging their strengths.
  • For reference, review the following materials:
  • From the required text,HBR On Strategy Vol. 2:Pipelines, Platforms & the New Rules (Van Alstyne, et al., 2016)

Pipelines, Platforms & the New Rules (Van Alstyne, et al., 2016)

BACK IN 2007 the five major mobile-phone manufacturersNokia, Samsung, Motorola, Sony Ericsson, and LGcollectively controlled 90% of the industry's global profits. That year, Apple's iPhone burst onto the scene and began gobbling up market share.

By 2015 the iPhone single-handedly generated 92% of global prof- its, while all but one of the former incumbents made no profit at all. How can we explain the iPhone's rapid domination of its indus- try? And how can we explain its competitors' free fall? Nokia and the others had classic strategic advantages that should have pro- tected them: strong product differentiation, trusted brands, leading operating systems, excellent logistics, protective regulation, huge R&D budgets, and massive scale. For the most part, those firms

looked stable, profitable, and well entrenched.

Certainly the iPhone had an innovative design and novel capa- bilities. But in 2007, Apple was a weak, nonthreatening player sur- rounded by 800-pound gorillas. It had less than 4% of market share in desktop operating systems and none at all in mobile phones.

As we'll explain, Apple (along with Google's competing Android system) overran the incumbents by exploiting the power of

101

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

platforms and leveraging the new rules of strategy they give rise to. Platform businesses bring together producers and consumers in high-value exchanges. Their chief assets are information and inter- actions, which together are also the source of the value and their competitive advantage.

Understanding this, Apple conceived the iPhone and its operating system as more than a product or a conduit for services. It imagined them as a way to connect participants in two-sided marketsapp developers on one side and app users on the othergenerating value for both groups. As the number of participants on each side grew, that value increaseda phenomenon called "network effects," which is central to platform strategy. By January 2015 the company's App Store offered 1.4 million apps and had cumulatively generated

$25 billion for developers.

Apple's success in building a platform business within a conven- tional product firm holds critical lessons for companies across in- dustries. Firms that fail to create platforms and don't learn the new rules of strategy will be unable to compete for long.

Pipeline to Platform

Platforms have existed for years. Malls link consumers and mer- chants; newspapers connect subscribers and advertisers. What's changed in this century is that information technology has pro- foundly reduced the need to own physical infrastructure and as- sets. IT makes building and scaling up platforms vastly simpler and cheaper, allows nearly frictionless participation that strengthens network effects, and enhances the ability to capture, analyze, and exchange huge amounts of data that increase the platform's value to all. You don't need to look far to see examples of platform busi- nesses, from Uber to Alibaba to Airbnb, whose spectacular growth abruptly upended their industries.

Though they come in many varieties, platforms all have an eco- system with the same basic structure, comprising four types of play- ers. The owners of platforms control their intellectual property and governance. Providers serve as the platforms' interface with users.

102

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

Idea in Brief

The Sea Change

Platform businesses that bring to- gether producers and consumers, as Uber and Airbnb do, are gob- bling up market share and trans- forming competition. Traditional businesses that fail to create plat- forms and to learn the new rules of strategy will struggle.

The New Rules

With a platform, the critical asset is the community and the resources of its members. The focus of strategy shifts from controlling to orchestrating

resources, from optimizing in- ternal processes to facilitating external interactions, and from in- creasing customer value to maxi- mizing ecosystem value.

The Upshot

In this new world, competition can emerge from seemingly unrelated industries or from within the plat- form itself. Firms must make smart choices about whom to let onto platforms and what they're al- lowed to do there, and must track new metrics designed to monitor and boost platform interactions.

Producers create their offerings, and consumers use those offerings.

To understand how the rise of platforms is transforming com- petition, we need to examine how platforms differ from the con- ventional "pipeline" businesses that have dominated industry for decades. Pipeline businesses create value by controlling a linear se- ries of activitiesthe classic value-chain model. Inputs at one end of the chain (say, materials from suppliers) undergo a series of steps that transform them into an output that's worth more: the finished product. Apple's handset business is essentially a pipeline. But com- bine it with the App Store, the marketplace that connects app devel- opers and iPhone owners, and you've got a platform.

As Apple demonstrates, firms needn't be only a pipeline or a plat- form; they can be both. While plenty of pure pipeline businesses are still highly competitive, when platforms enter the same market- place, the platforms virtually always win. That's why pipeline giants such as Walmart, Nike, John Deere, and GE are all scrambling to in- corporate platforms into their models.

103

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

The players in a platform ecosystem

A platform provides the infrastructure and rules for a marketplace that brings together producers and consumers. The players in the ecosystem ll fourmain roles but may shift rapidly from one role to another. Understanding the relationships both within and outside the ecosystem is central to platform strategy.

Creators of the platform's oerings (for example, apps

on Android)

Buyers or users of the oerings

Value and data exchange and feedback

Interfaces for the platform (mobiledevices are

providerson Android)

Providers

Owner Platform

Controller of platform IP and arbiter of who may participate and in what ways (Google owns Android)

The move from pipeline to platform involves three key shifts:

1. From resource control to resource orchestration. The re- source-based view of competition holds that firms gain advantageby controlling scarce and valuableideally, inimitableassets. Ina pipeline world, those include tangible assets such as mines andreal estate and intangible assets like intellectual property. With plat- forms, the assets that are hard to copy are the community and the resources its members own and contribute, be they rooms or cars

104

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

or ideas and information. In other words, the network of producers and consumers is the chief asset.

2.From internal optimization to external interaction. Pipeline firms organize their internal labor and resources to create value by optimizing an entire chain of product activities, from materials sourcing to sales and service. Platforms create value by facilitating interactions between external producers and consumers. Because of this external orientation, they often shed even variable costs of pro- duction. The emphasis shifts from dictating processes to persuading participants, and ecosystem governance becomes an essential skill.

3.From a focus on customer value to a focus on ecosystem value. Pipelines seek to maximize the lifetime value of individual custom- ers of products and services, who, in effect, sit at the end of a lin-ear process. By contrast, platforms seek to maximize the total value of an expanding ecosystem in a circular, iterative, feedback-driven process. Sometimes that requires subsidizing one type of consumer in order to attract another type.

These three shifts make clear that competition is more complicated and dynamic in a platform world. The competitive forces described by Michael Porter (the threat of new entrants and substitute products or services, the bargaining power of customers and suppliers, and the in- tensity of competitive rivalry) still apply. But on platforms these forces behave differently, and new factors come into play. To manage them, executives must pay close attention to the interactions on the plat- form, participants' access, and new performance metrics.

We'll examine each of these in turn. But first let's look more closely at network effectsthe driving force behind every success- ful platform.

The Power of Network Eects

The engine of the industrial economy was, and remains, supply- side economies of scale. Massive fixed costs and low marginal costs mean that firms achieving higher sales volume than their

105

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

competitors have a lower average cost of doing business. That al- lows them to reduce prices, which increases volume further, which permits more price cutsa virtuous feedback loop that produces monopolies. Supply economics gave us Carnegie Steel, Edison Elec- tric (which became GE), Rockefeller's Standard Oil, and many other industrial era giants.

In supply-side economies, firms achieve market power by con- trolling resources, ruthlessly increasing efficiency, and fending off challenges from any of the five forces. The goal of strategy in this world is to build a moat around the business that protects it from competition and channels competition toward other firms.

The driving force behind the internet economy, conversely, is demand-side economies of scale, also known as network effects. These are enhanced by technologies that create efficiencies in social networking, demand aggregation, app development, and other phenomena that help networks expand. In the internet economy, firms that achieve higher "volume" than competitors (that is, attract more platform participants) offer a higher average value per transac- tion. That's because the larger the network, the better the matches between supply and demand and the richer the data that can be used to find matches. Greater scale generates more value, which at- tracts more participants, which creates more valueanother virtu- ous feedback loop that produces monopolies. Network effects gave

us Alibaba, which accounts for over 75% of Chinese e-commerce transactions; Google, which accounts for 82% of mobile operating systems and 94% of mobile search; and Facebook, the world's domi- nant social platform.

The five forces model doesn't factor in network effects and the value they create. It regards external forces as "depletive," or ex- tracting value from a firm, and so argues for building barriers against them. In demand-side economies, however, external forces can be "accretive"adding value to the platform business. Thus the power of suppliers and customers, which is threatening in a supply-side world, may be viewed as an asset on platforms. Understanding when external forces may either add or extract value in an ecosys- tem is central to platform strategy.

106

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

How Platforms Change Strategy

In pipeline businesses, the five forces are relatively defined and sta- ble. If you're a cement manufacturer or an airline, your customers and competitive set are fairly well understood, and the boundaries separating your suppliers, customers, and competitors are reason- ably clear. In platform businesses, those boundaries can shift rap- idly, as we'll discuss.

Forces within the ecosystem

Platform participantsconsumers, producers, and providers typically create value for a business. But they may defect if they be- lieve their needs can be met better elsewhere. More worrisome, they may turn on the platform and compete directly with it. Zynga began as a games producer on Facebook but then sought to migrate players onto its own platform. Amazon and Samsung, providers of devices for the Android platform, tried to create their own versions of the operating system and take consumers with them.

The new roles that players assume can be either accretive or de- pletive. For example, consumers and producers can swap roles in ways that generate value for the platform. Users can ride with Uber today and drive for it tomorrow; travelers can stay with Airbnb one night and serve as hosts for other customers the next. In contrast, providers on a platform may become depletive, especially if they de- cide to compete with the owner. Netflix, a provider on the platforms of telecommunication firms, has control of consumers' interactions with the content it offers, so it can extract value from the platform owners while continuing to rely on their infrastructure.

As a consequence, platform firms must constantly encourage accretive activity within their ecosystems while monitoring partic- ipants' activity that may prove depletive. This is a delicate gover- nance challenge that we'll discuss further.

Forces exerted by ecosystems

Managers of pipeline businesses can fail to anticipate platform competition from seemingly unrelated industries. Yet successful platform businesses tend to move aggressively into new terrain

107

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

PIPELINE FIRMS HAVE LONG outsourced aspects of their internal functions, such as customer service. But today companies are taking that shift even fur- ther, moving toward orchestrating external networks that can complement or entirely replace the activities of once-internal functions.

Inversion extends outsourcing: Where rms might once have furnished de- sign specications to a known supplier, they now tap ideas they haven't yet imagined from third parties they don't even know. Firms are being turned inside out as value-creating activities move beyond their direct control and their organizational boundaries.

Marketing is no longer just about creating internally managed outbound messages. It now extends to the creation and propagation of messages by consumers themselves. Travel destination marketers invite consumers to submit videos of their trips and promote them on social media. The online eyeglasses retailer Warby Parker encourages consumers to post online pho- tos of themselves modeling dierent styles and ask friends to help them choose. Consumers get more-attering glasses, and Warby Parker gets viral exposure.

Information technology, historically focused on managing internal enterprise systems, increasingly supports external social and community networks. Threadless, a producer of T-shirts, coordinates communication not just to and from but among customers, who collaborate to develop the best product designs.

and into what were once considered separate industries with little warning. Google has moved from web search into mapping, mobile operating systems, home automation, driverless cars, and voice rec- ognition. As a result of such shape-shifting, a platform can abruptly transform an incumbent's set of competitors. Swatch knows how to compete with Timex on watches but now must also compete with Apple. Siemens knows how to compete with Honeywell in thermo- stats but now is being challenged by Google's Nest.

Competitive threats tend to follow one of three patterns. First, they may come from an established platform with superior net- work effects that uses its relationships with customers to enter your industry. Products have features; platforms have communities, and those communities can be leveraged. Given Google's relation-

108

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

Human resources functions at companies increasingly leverage the wisdom of networks to augment internal talent. Enterprise software giant SAP has opened the internal system on which its developers exchange problems and solutions to its external ecosystemto developers at both its own partners and its partners' clients. Information sharing across this network has improved product development and productivity and reduced support costs.

Finance, which historically has recorded its activities on private internal accounts, now records some transactions externally on public, or "distrib- uted," ledgers. Organizations such as IBM, Intel, and JPMorgan are adopting blockchain technology that allows ledgers to be securely shared and vetted by anyone with permission. Participants can inspect everything from aggre- gated accounts to individual transactions. This allows rms to, for example, crowdsource compliance with accounting principles or seek input on their nancial management from a broad network outside the company. Opening the books this way taps the wisdom of crowds and signals trustworthiness.

Operations and logistics traditionally emphasize the management of just- in-time inventory. More and more often, that function is being supplanted by the management of "not even mine" inventorywhether rooms, apps, or other assets owned by network participants. Indeed, if Marriott, Yellow Cab, and NBC had added platforms to their pipeline value chains, then Airbnb, Uber, and YouTube might never have come into being.

ship with consumers, the value its network provides them, and its interest in the internet of things, Siemens might have predicted the tech giant's entry into the home-automation market (though not necessarily into thermostats). Second, a competitor may target an overlapping customer base with a distinctive new offering that leverages network effects. Airbnb's and Uber's challenges to the hotel and taxi industries fall into this category. The final pattern, in which platforms that collect the same type of data that your firm does suddenly go after your market, is still emerging. When a data set is valuable, but different parties control different chunks of it, competition between unlikely camps may ensue. This is happening in health care, where traditional providers, producers of wearables like Fitbit, and retail pharmacies like Walgreens are all launching

109

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

platforms based on the health data they own. They can be expected to compete for control of a broader data setand the consumer rela- tionships that come with it.

Focus

Managers of pipeline businesses focus on growing sales. For them, goods and services delivered (and the revenues and profits from them) are the units of analysis. For platforms, the focus shifts to interactionsexchanges of value between producers and consum- ers on the platform. The unit of exchange (say, a view of a video or a thumbs-up on a post) can be so small that little or no money changes hands. Nevertheless, the number of interactions and the associated network effects are the ultimate source of competitive advantage.

With platforms, a critical strategic aim is strong up-front design that will attract the desired participants, enable the right interactions (so-called core interactions), and encourage ever-more-powerful network effects. In our experience, managers often fumble here by focusing too much on the wrong type of interaction. And the per- haps counterintuitive bottom line, given how much we stress the importance of network effects, is that it's usually wise to ensure the value of interactions for participants before focusing on volume.

Most successful platforms launch with a single type of interac- tion that generates high value even if, at first, low volume. They then move into adjacent markets or adjacent types of interactions, increasing both value and volume. Facebook, for example, launched with a narrow focus (connecting Harvard students to other Harvard students) and then opened the platform to college students broadly and ultimately to everyone. LinkedIn launched as a professional networking site and later entered new markets with recruitment, publishing, and other offerings.

Access and governance

In a pipeline world, strategy revolves around erecting barriers. With platforms, while guarding against threats remains critical, the focus of strategy shifts to eliminating barriers to production and consumption in order to maximize value creation. To that end,

110

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

POSITIVE SPILLOVER EFFECTS help platforms rapidly increase the volume of interactions. Book purchases on a platform, for example, generate book recommendations that create value for other participants on it, who then buy more books. This dynamic exploits the fact that network eects are often strongest among interactions of the same type (say, book sales) than among unrelated interactions (say, package pickup and yardwork in dierent cities mediated by the odd-job platform TaskRabbit).

Consider ride sharing. By itself, an individual ride on Uber is high value for both rider and drivera desirable core interaction. As the number of plat- form participants increases, so does the value Uber delivers to both sides of the market; it becomes easier for consumers to get rides and for drivers to nd fares. Spillover eects further enhance the value of Uber to participants: Data from riders' interactions with driversratings of drivers and ridersim- proves the value of the platform to other users. Similarly, data on how well a given ride matched a rider's needs helps determine optimal pricing across the platformanother important spillover eect.

platform executives must make smart choices about access (whom to let onto the platform) and governance (or "control"what con- sumers, producers, providers, and even competitors are allowed to do there).

Platforms consist of rules and architecture. Their owners need to decide how open both should be. An open architecture allows play- ers to access platform resources, such as app developer tools, and create new sources of value. Open governance allows players other than the owner to shape the rules of trade and reward sharing on the platform. Regardless of who sets the rules, a fair reward sys- tem is key. If managers open the architecture but do not share the rewards, potential platform participants (such as app developers) have the ability to engage but no incentives. If managers open the rules and rewards but keep the architecture relatively closed, poten- tial participants have incentives to engage but not the ability.

These choices aren't fixed. Platforms often launch with a fairly closed architecture and governance and then open up as they introduce new types of interactions and sources of value. But every

111

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

platform must induce producers and consumers to interact and share their ideas and resources. Effective governance will inspire outsiders to bring valuable intellectual property to the platform, as Zynga did in bringing FarmVille to Facebook. That won't happen if prospective partners fear exploitation.

Some platforms encourage producers to create high-value offerings on them by establishing a policy of "permissionless innovation." They let producers invent things for the platform without approval but guarantee the producers will share in the value created. Rovio, for example, didn't need permission to create the Angry Birds game on the Apple operating system and could be confident that Apple wouldn't steal its IP. The result was a hit that generated enormous value for all participants on the platform. However, Google's Android platform has allowed even more innovation to flourish by being more open at the provider layer. That decision is one reason Google's market capitalization surpassed Apple's in early 2016 (just as Microsoft's did in the 1980s).

However, unfettered access can destroy value by creating "noise"misbehavior or excess or low-quality content that inhib- its interaction. One company that ran into this problem was Chat- roulette, which paired random people from around the world for webchats. It grew exponentially until noise caused its abrupt col- lapse. Initially utterly openit had no access rules at allit soon en- countered the "naked hairy man" problem, which is exactly what it sounds like. Clothed users abandoned the platform in droves. Chatrou- lette responded by reducing its openness with a variety of user filters.

Most successful platforms similarly manage openness to maxi- mize positive network effects. Airbnb and Uber rate and insure hosts and drivers, Twitter and Facebook provide users with tools to pre- vent stalking, and Apple's App Store and the Google Play store both filter out low-quality applications.

Metrics

Leaders of pipeline enterprises have long focused on a narrow set of metrics that capture the health of their businesses. For example, pipelines grow by optimizing processes and opening bottlenecks;

112

PIPELINES, PLATFORMS, AND THE NEW RULES OF STRATEGY

one standard metric, inventory turnover, tracks the flow of goods and services through them. Push enough goods through and get margins high enough, and you'll see a reasonable rate of return.

As pipelines launch platforms, however, the numbers to watch change. Monitoring and boosting the performance of core inter- actions becomes critical. Here are new metrics managers need to track:

Interaction failure. If a traveler opens the Lyft app and sees "no cars available," the platform has failed to match an intent to con- sume with supply. Failures like these directly diminish network effects. Passengers who see this message too often will stop using Lyft, leading to higher driver downtimes, which can cause drivers to quit Lyft, resulting in even lower ride availability. Feedback loops can strengthen or weaken a platform.

Engagement. Healthy platforms track the participation of eco- system members that enhances network effectsactivities such as content sharing and repeat visits. Facebook, for example, watches the ratio of daily to monthly users to gauge the effectiveness of its efforts to increase engagement.

Match quality. Poor matches between the needs of users and pro- ducers weaken network effects. Google constantly monitors users' clicking and reading to refine how its search results fill their requests.

Negative network eects. Badly managed platforms often suffer from other kinds of problems that create negative feedback loops and reduce value. For example, congestion caused by unconstrained network growth can discourage participation. So can misbehavior, as Chatroulette found. Managers must watch for negative network effects and use governance tools to stem them by, for example, with- holding privileges or banishing troublemakers.

Finally, platforms must understand the financial value of their communities and their network effects. Consider that in 2016, pri- vate equity markets placed the value of Uber, a demand economy

113

VAN ALSTYNE, PARKER, AND CHOUDARY

firm founded in 2009, above that of GM, a supply economy firm founded in 1908. Clearly Uber's investors were looking beyond the traditional financials and metrics when calculating the firm's worth and potential. This is a clear indication that the rules have changed.

Because platforms require new approaches to strategy, they also demand new leadership styles. The skills it takes to tightly control internal resources just don't apply to the job of nurturing external ecosystems.

While pure platforms naturally launch with an external orientation, traditional pipeline firms must develop new core competenciesand a new mind-setto design, govern, and nimbly expand platforms on top of their existing businesses. The inability to make this leap ex- plains why some traditional business leaders with impressive track records falter in platforms. Media mogul Rupert Murdoch bought the social network Myspace and managed it the way he might have run a newspaperfrom the top down, bureaucratically, and with a focus more on controlling the internal operation than on fostering the eco- system and creating value for participants. In time the Myspace com- munity dissipated and the platform withered.

The failure to transition to a new approach explains the precari- ous situation that traditional businessesfrom hotels to health care providers to taxisfind themselves in. For pipeline firms, the writing is on the wall: Learn the new rules of strategy for a platform world, or begin planning your exit.

Originally published in April 2016. Reprint R1604C

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image

Step: 3

blur-text-image

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Mathematical Economics

Authors: Wade Hands, D Wade Hands

2nd Edition

0195133781, 9780195133783

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions

Question

Why are positive stereotypes harmful?

Answered: 1 week ago