Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

Question 1 and 2 please in details Question 2 (20 points) Consider an economy that consists of two islands, i = {1, 2). Each island

Question 1 and 2 please in details

image text in transcribedimage text in transcribed
Question 2 (20 points) Consider an economy that consists of two islands, i = {1, 2). Each island has a large population of infinitely-lived, identical agents, normalized to the unit. There is a unique consumption good, say, coconuts, which is not storable across periods. Although within each island agents have identical preferences over consumption, across islands there is a difference: Agents in island 2 are more patient. More precisely, the lifetime utility for the typical agent in island i is given by U. ((c).) = EB; In(c), 1=0 where B, E (0, 1), for all i, and B2 > 81. Due to weather conditions in this economy, island 1 has a production of e > 0 units of coconuts in even periods and zero otherwise, and island 2 has a production of e units of coconuts in odd periods and zero otherwise. Agents cannot do anything to boost this production, but they can trade coconuts, so that the consumption of the typical agent in island i, in period t, is not necessarily equal to the production of coconuts on that island in that period (which may very well be zero). Assume that shipping coconuts across islands is costless. a) Describe the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium (ADE) allocations in this economy. You can use any method you like, but I strongly recommend that you exploit Negishi's method. b) Describe the ADE prices in this economy. c) Plot the equilibrium allocation for the typical agent in island i, i.e., {@), i = {1, 2), against t. Is there any period t in which & = &? If yes, please provide closed form solution for that value of t.*Question 1 (20 points) Consider the standard Mortensen-Pissarides model in continuous time. Labor force is normalized to 1. Unemployed workers with measure u search for jobs, and firms with measure v search for unemployed workers. The matching technology is given by the function m(u, v), which is increasing in both arguments and exhibits constant returns to scale. It is convenient to define the market tightness 0 = v/u. A large measure of firms decide whether to enter the labor market with exactly one vacancy. When a firm meets an unemployed worker a job is formed. The output of a job is p per unit of time. However, while the vacancy is unfilled, firms have to pay a search or recruiting cost equal to pc per unit of time. Upon a successful match, the worker's wage is negotiated through Nash bargaining. Let / represent the worker's bargaining power. The destruction rate of existing jobs is exogenous and given by the Poison rate 1. Once a shock arrives, the firm closes the job down. Subsequently, the worker goes back to the pool of unemployment, and the firm exits the labor market. So far this is just the model we described in class. What is new here is that unemployed workers are not (necessarily) eligible for unemployment benefits for the whole duration of their unemployment spell. More precisely, a worker who just lost her job starts receiving a benefit z per unit of time right away, but she will stop being eligible for this benefit at a Poisson rate o. Thus, at any point in time, there are two types of unemployed workers: those who are still eligible for z, and those whose unemployment benefit eligibility has expired. This, of course, will be important for the negotiation process between a firm and an unemployed worker.' Throughout this question focus on steady state equilibria and let the discount rate of agents be given by r. Also, assume that 6 2 A, which will simplify some of the derivations later on. a) Draw a figure that describes the flows in and out of the various states a worker may be in. Denote these states by E, for employed, U, for unemployed with benefits, and Un, for unemployed without benefits. b) Let u denote the equilibrium measure of all unemployed workers, and u. the measure of unemployed workers who do not receive benefits. Equating the inflows and outflows for the states E and Un (defined in part a), derive the analogue of the Beveridge curve for this economy. That is, find two equations that describe the equilibrium variables u, u, as functions of the market tightness 0. In what follows let w denote the wage of a worker who got a job while still eligible for unemployment benefits, and let w, denote the wage of a worker who was not eligible for unemployment benefits when she negotiated with the firm. It should be obvious why: even though the two types of unemployed workers have the exact same bargaining power (8), they do not have the same outside option. c) Describe the value functions for a worker in the various states. d) Describe the value functions for a firm in the various states. e) Exploiting the free entry of firms into the labor market, describe the Job Creation (JC) condition for this economy." f) Solve the bargaining problem between a firm and an unemployed worker in state U and Un and derive the analogue of the Wage Curve (WC) for this economy. g) Using your findings in part (f) show that, for any given 0, we have w > w.. What is the economic meaning of this result? h) Without going into detail, provide a strategy to solve for the steady state equi- librium. More precisely, explain how you would combine the various equilibrium con- ditions derived so far in order to characterize the five equilibrium variables

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image_2

Step: 3

blur-text-image_3

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions