Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

read The Wealth and Poverty of Nations, by David Landes, and read pages 207-210. Based on your reading of Chapter 3, Economic Decision Makers, explain

image text in transcribedimage text in transcribed

read "The Wealth and Poverty of Nations", by David Landes, and read pages 207-210. Based on your reading of Chapter 3, "Economic Decision Makers", explain in detail how you interpret Landes's story about mechanization using the ideas developed in this chapter.

image text in transcribedimage text in transcribed
Pg209 thoung to large workshops where spinners and weavers would have to turn up on time and work the full day under supervision. That was no small matter. Cottage industry. after all. had great advantages for the merchant-manufacturer. in particular. low cost of entry and low over-head. Inthis mode. it was the worker who supplied plant and equipment. and If business slowed. the putter-out could simply turn off the orders. Large shops or plants. on the other hand, called for a substantial capital investment: land and buildings to start with. plus machines. Putting-out, moreover, was popular with everybody. The workers liked the freedom from discipline. the privilege of stopping and going as they pleased. Work rhythms reflected this independence. Weavers typically rested and played long. well into the week. then worked hard toward the end in order to make delivery and collect pay on Saturday. On Fridays they might work through the night. Saturday night was for drinking and Sunday brought more beer and ale. Monday (Saint Monday) was equally holy, and Tuesday was needed to recover from so much holiness. Such conict within the industrywhat a Mandst might call its internal contradictionsled logically.then. to the gathering of workers under one roof, there to labor under surveillance and supervision. But manufacturers found that they had to pay to persuade people out of cottages and into mills. So long as the equipment in the mill was the same as in the cottage. mill production cost more. The only operations where this law did not hold was in heat-using technologies (fulling. brewing. glassmaking, ironmaking, and the like). There the savings yielded by concentration (one hearth as against many) more than compensated for the capital costs! Efforts to concentrate labor in textile manufacture, however, which went back in England to the sixteenth century, invariably failed. They did better in Europe, where governments tried to promote industry by subsidizing and assigning labor to large hand-powered shop "manufactories' or 'protofactories.' But this was an articial prosperity, and the withdrawal of support spelled bankruptcy. It took power machinery to make the factory competitive. Power made it possible to drive larger and more efficient machines. thus underselling the cottage product by ever bigger margins. The hand spinners went quickly; the hand weavers more slowly. but surely. In spite * The Chinese Communist regime leamed this later when it tried to make ago of backyard blast furnaces. Pg21o of higher wages. the mills still seemed a prison to the old-timers. Where. then. did the early millowners nd their labor force? Where else but among those who could not say no? In England that meant children. often conscripted (bought) from the poorhouses, and women, especially the young unmarneds. On the Continent.the manufacturers were able to negotiate for convict labor and military personnel. So was born what Karl Marx called "Modern Industry." fruit of a marriage between machines and power: also between power (force and energy) and power (political). THE WEALTH AND POVERTY OF NATIONS Pg207 This was a factory, comparable in almost every way to the cotton mills of a later era. Almost. .. the difference was that the Lombe mill at Derby, along with the hand-operated throwsters' shops that had preceded it and some smaller machine imitators, was more than enough to accommodate England's demand for silk yarn. Silk, after all, was a cosdy raw material, and the silk manufacture catered to a small and affluent clientele. So the Lombe mill, fifty years ahead of those first cotton mills of the 1770s, was not the model for a new mode of production. One could not get an industrial revolution out of silk. 19 Wool and cotton were something else again. When wool sneezed, all Europe caught cold; cotton, and the whole world fell ill. Wool was much the more important in Europe, and cotton's role in the Industrial Revolution was in some ways an accident. The British "calico acts" (1700 and 1721), which prohibited the import and even wearing of East Indian prints and dyestuffs, were intended to protect the native woolen and linen manufacturers, but inadvertently sheltered the still infant cotton industry; and while cotton was a lusty infant, it was still much smaller than the older branches at midcentury. The first attempts to build spinning machines aimed at wool, because that was where the profit lay. But when wool fibers proved troublesome and cotton docile, inventors turned their attention to the easier material. Also, the encrustation of the woolen industry and the vested power of its workforce impeded change. Cotton, growing fast, recruiting new hands, found it easier to impose new ways. This is a constant of technological innovation as process: it is much easier to teach novelty to inexperienced workers than to teach old dogs new tricks.* Why the interest in mechanization? Primarily because the growth of the textile industry was beginning to outstrip labor supply.* England * On the resistance of workers in wool to mechanization , see especially Randall, Before the Luddites, who points out this respons e was also a function of organization and the sharing of gain. Where the workers were in effect independentagents, as in York-shire, they had little trouble adopting new ways that profited them ; where they served as wag e labor , as in the West Country , they fought machine s that threatened employment. The first in the series of spinning machines that laid the foundation of the factory system was that of Lewis Paul and John Wyatt (patented in Paul's name) in 1738 . The key invention her e was the us e of rollers turning at different speeds for drawing out the fiber-a feature that became thereafter a regular component of spinning machines fitted with a flyer or equivalent. At that time, we are told, the shortage of spinning labor was nothing like what it would become in another generation; in the words of Pg208 had jumped ahead on the strength of rural manufacture (putting-out), but the dispersion of activity across hill and dale was driving up costs of distribution and collection. Meanwhile, trying to meet demand, employers raised wages, that is, they increased the price they paid for finished work. To their dismay, however, the higher income simply permitted workers more time for leisure, and the supply of work actually diminished. Merchant-manufacturers found themselves on a treadmill. In defiance of all their natural instincts, they came to wish for higher food prices. Perhaps a rise in the cost of living would compel spinners and weavers to their task.* The workers, however, did respond to market incentives. They were contractors as well as wage laborers, and this dual status gave them opportunity for self-enrichment at the expense of the putter-out. Spinners and weavers would take materials from one merchant and then sell the finished article to a competitor, stalling now one, now another, and juggling their obligations to a fare-thee-well. They also learned to set some of the raw material aside for their own use: no backward-bending supply curve when working for their own gain. Trying to conceal the embezzlement, weavers made thinner, poorer fabrics and filled them out by artifice or additive. The manufacturer in turn tried to discourage such theft by closely examining each piece and if necessary "abating" the price of the finished article. This conflict of interests gave rise to a costly cold war between employer and employed. The manufacturers clamored for help from the civil authorities. They called for the right to inflict corporal punishment on laggards and deadbeats (no use trying to fine them); also the right to enter the weavers' cottages without warrant and search for embezzled materials. These demands got nowhere. An Englishman's home was his castle, sacred. Little wonder, then, that frustrated manufacturers turned their Wadsworth an d Mann, hardly serious-The Cotton Trade, p. 414 . Yet the unevenness of the yarn produced by hand spinners-both the individual's work and from one spinner to the next- meant that weavers had to buy far more yarn than they actually used in order to have enough of a given quality. The machine promised to end that - Ibid., p. 416. * These constraints were the more vexatious in a context of rising consumer demand . The growing appetite for things should have increased the supply of labor ; and so it did in the long run . But in the short, demand got ahead of supply, and manufacturers got impatient. On the link between consumption and industry, see de Vries, "Industrial Revolution. " Pg209 thoughts to large workshops where spinners and weavers would have to turn up on time and work the full day under supervision. That was no small matter. Cottage industry, after all, had great advantages for the merchant-manufacturer, in particular, low cost of entry and low over-head. In this mode, it was the worker who supplied plant and equipment, and if business slowed, the putter-out could simply turn off the orders. Large shops or plants, on the other hand, called for a substantial capital investment: land and buildings to start with, plus machines

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image

Step: 3

blur-text-image

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Macroeconomics

Authors: Charles I. Jones

4th Edition

393603767, 393603768, 9780393616125 , 978-0393603767

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions

Question

3. How much information do we need to collect?

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

2. What types of information are we collecting?

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

5. How quickly can we manage to collect the information?

Answered: 1 week ago