Question
Should cities and towns charge for each use of a street? An article in The Economist (June 23, 2018) talked about how public transit is
Should cities and towns charge for each use of a street? An article in The Economist (June 23, 2018) talked about how public transit is "ailing" in many cities. The article discusses various options for people to get around in cities such as public transportation, personal cars, cycling, and app-based ride-hailing services. Whatever type of transportation exists, it must be paid for. And in all cases, transportation in cities and towns relies on the existence of streets (or rails in the case of subway systems). After considering ways to reduce congestion and pollution, the Economist article states: "It would be much better to charge for each use of a road, with higher prices for busy ones."
Read "Off the rails: How to stop the decline of public transport in rich countries," The Economist, June 23, 2018.
Questions to Think About:
1. How are streets paid for in your city or town?
2. Do you agree or disagree with The Economist that it would be better for people to pay for streets each time they use one? Why?
3. What are the advantages and disadvantages of collective financing vs. individual payment for essential things everyone needs and that we use every day?
4. What are your thoughts on electric vehicle charging stations and their incorporation into public infrastructure spending?
How to Stop the Decline of Public Transport in Rich Countries
Co-opt the competition from Uber and other app-base firms
To those who have to squeeze onto the number 25 bus in London, or the A train in New York, the change might not be noticeable. But public transport is becoming less busy in those cities, and in others besides. Passenger numbers are flat or falling in almost every American metropolis, and in some Canadian and European ones, too. That is despite healthy growth in urban populations and employment. Nose-to-armpit travellers may be even more surprised to hear that the emptying of public transport is a problem.
Although transport agencies blame their unpopularity on things like roadworks and broken signals, it seems more likely that they are being outcompeted (seearticle). App-based taxi services like Uber and Lyft are more comfortable and convenient than trains or buses. Cycling is nicer than it was, and rental bikes are more widely available. Cars are cheap to buy, thanks to cut-rate loans, and ever cheaper to run. Online shopping, home working and office-sharing mean more people can avoid travelling altogether.
The competition is only likely to grow. More than one laboratory is churning out new transport technologies and applications (seearticle). Silicon Valley invented Uber and, more recently, apps that let people rent electric scooters and then abandon them on the pavement. China created dockless bicycles and battery-powered "e-bikes", both of which are spreading. Some inventions will fail, or will be regulated out of existence (at one point, Segways were the future). But new ideas, including driverless taxis, are coming around the corner. Mass transport is much less nimble. As New York's Second Avenue subway, London's Crossrail and Amsterdam's North-South metro line have shown, building new train lines is now incredibly complicated and expensive.
This is a headache for the operators of public-transport systems. It is also a problem for cities. Like it or not and many people do not mass public transport does some things very well. It provides a service for people who are too old, too young, too poor, too fearful or too drunk to drive or ride a bike. Trains and subways cause less pollution than cars and move people at far higher densities. The danger is that public transport could become a rump service, ever less popular and ever less good, partly because of its unpopularity. Fewer passengers mean fewer trains and buses, which leads to longer waits for those who persist with them. Cars, whether driven or driverless, will clog the roads.
To some extent, that dystopian future can be seen off by pricing road use properly. Many cities, particularly in America, generously subsidise driving by forcing developers to provide lots of parking spaces. Elsewhere, cities have created congestion-charging zones. But that is a hopelessly crude tool. Most congestion zones in effect sell daily tickets to drive around as much as you like within the zone and charge nothing to vehicles such as taxis and minicabs. It would be much better to charge for each use of a road, with higher prices for busy ones.
Transport agencies should also embrace the upstarts, and copy them. Cities tend either to ignore app-based services or to try to push them off the streets. That is understandable, given the rules-are-for-losers attitude of firms like Uber. But it is an error. Although new forms of transport often compete with old ones in city centres, they ought to complement each other in the suburbs. Taxi services and e-bikes could get people to and from railway stations and bus stops, which are often inconveniently far apart outside the urban core.
She's got a ticket to ride, but she doesn't care
It is doubtful that most people make hard distinctions between public and private transport. They just want to get somewhere, and there is a cost in time, money and comfort. An ideal system would let them move across a city for a single payment, transferring from trains to taxis to bicycles as needed. Building a platform to allow that is hard, and requires much sweet-talking of legacy networks as well as technology firms though a few cities, like Helsinki and Birmingham, in England, are trying. It is probably the secret to keeping cities moving.
Step by Step Solution
There are 3 Steps involved in it
Step: 1
Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions
See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success
Step: 2
Step: 3
Ace Your Homework with AI
Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance
Get Started