Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

The Joy of Economics: Making Sense out of Life Robert J. Stonebraker, Winthrop University Important note: Because I am about to retire, my university plans

The Joy of Economics: Making Sense out of Life Robert J. Stonebraker, Winthrop University Important note: Because I am about to retire, my university plans to remove this site from its server. As a result, this page might not be available after May 15, 2017. If you wish to continue accessing the material, feel free to copy it (with appropriate citation) or move it to another site or venue. Sacrifice and Stigma The greatest vicissitude of things among men is the vicissitude of sects. .....Sir Francis Bacon My former Lutheran congregation once voted to call an Assistant Pastor. The meeting was mercifully short and the vote predictably lopsided. A known curmudgeon citing financial concerns voiced the lone dissent. Could our budget handle this extra expense? Would weekly offerings be adequate? Treasurer Thorsen took the floor and assured us not to worry. Parishioners would rise to the challenge and plans for a new stewardship campaign, including an Every Member Visit, already were underway. Begging for bucks Every Member Visit. Even typing the phrase curls my toes and sparks involuntary facial tics. As a young adult I agreed to join my congregation's campaign. The goals were simple: visit every household in the congregation, deliver offering envelopes for the coming year, and secure a financial pledge. After a brief training session, I was assigned four households. A cinch. Armed with pledge cards, boxes of envelopes and copies of budget plans, I marched into battle on the appointed Sunday. To ease into the fray, I began with an easy mark. I chose an elderly parishioner who lived down the block and with whom I often shared pleasantries on evening walks around the neighborhood. Big mistake. My sheaf of pledge cards might as well have been a semi-automatic weapon. I could not get past the front door. Her normal smiles hardened into open hostility and I unceremoniously was routed from her porch. No admittance. No pledge. It was months before she again returned my evening greetings. Couple number two was wary, but let me through the door. They invited me to sit down and listened politely before refusing to make a pledge. "We don't do that," was their response, followed, as I stood to leave, by a "the church wastes too much money" zinger. The husband began muttering something that about "long-winded sermons," but I continued toward the door dodging deftly lest other barbs be hurled in my general direction. My third visit went more smoothly. The family chose not to answer the door. I left the offering The Joy of Economics http://faculty.winthrop.edu/stonebrakerr/book/stigma.htm 1 of 5 5/3/17, 9:27 PM envelopes inside the storm door with an "I'm sorry I missed you" note. Were they out? Or were they lurking in the den waiting for me to leave? I will never know. But the family cars all were in the garage. The day did end on a more positive note. The Lacey's, my last family, welcomed me warmly, offered me freshly baked goodies, engaged in an animated discussion of congregational mission, and made a generous financial pledge. If only the other families had welcomed me so enthusiastically. If only our other parishioners were as committed as the Lacey's. If only. Large congregations My congregation was a moderately large one. We had over 1,000 members, but were lucky to find 300 at worship on a particular Sunday. Ushers scrambled to set up extra chairs for overflow crowds each Christmas Eve and Easter but, on other Sundays, attendance dipped and choir anthems bounced off rows of empty pews. Being large does bring benefits. Multiple staff members support a diversified menu of programs and interest groups that smaller congregations can only imagine. And there are cost advantages as well. Attendance at liturgies, Sunday school classes, youth groups, and Bible studies rarely approaches physical capacity. Stuffing in extra participants almost always lowers the cost per person. Even when capacity is strained, constructing larger facilities often generates economies of scale. A building large enough to handle 1,000 parishioners is not likely to be twice as expensive as one built to accommodate 500.1 But bigness can be a bane as well as a blessing. Religious groups are often beset by free riders, members who happily consume services but who run for cover when Every Member Visit volunteers knock at the front door. Large congregations are especially vulnerable. The larger the group, the easier it is to hide. Shirking one's proportionate responsibilities is tough in a group of two, but easy in a group of 2,000. For those interested in marginal commitment only, large churches are the place to be. Free riders create at least two distinct problems for a religious congregation. First, free riders can be expensive; they raise costs for the more committed members. Free riders might duck when the offering plates pass by, but they seldom are shy about demanding services, and often complain the loudest when such services are slow in coming. Clerics of every stripe can identify dysfunctional families that rarely attend services or contribute funds, yet place disproportionate demands on their time and energy. Second, free riders demoralize other members of the congregation. If all members were as committed as the fore-mentioned Lacey's, Every-Member-Visits would be a breeze. It is the uncommitted free riders who cause me to equate such stewardship drives with root canals. And there's more. Worship services are not discrete spectator events. They are chapters in a congregation's continuing and collective journey of faith. Free-riding members who deign to drop in sporadically impede that journey. Occasional participants do not appreciate where the congregation has been or where it is going. Like derelict students who have skipped two weeks of class, they sit in the back row with dazed expressions of confusion. They do not sing with enthusiasm because the melodies and responses are unfamiliar. They do not pray with conviction because their own commitment is marginal. They do not seek out and greet new visitors because they cannot identify which people are visitors. Committed believers add excitement to worship. Free riders suck it right back out. Sacrifice and stigma The Joy of Economics http://faculty.winthrop.edu/stonebrakerr/book/stigma.htm 2 of 5 5/3/17, 9:27 PM What can a church do? How can it create a congregation of committed and enthusiastic members? To an economist, the answer is obvious. Change the relative price. When the price of Pepsi rises, its less-committed adherents switch to Coke. When the price of tickets to Disney World rises, the less-committed stay home and watch television. So it is with religion. Want to weed out less-committed members? Raise the price. What? Prices? Religion? Churches do not charge prices. Or do they? Congregations may not herd members through check-out aisles at the exits, but they do charge prices. The prices charged are not in the usual monetary terms. According to Laurence Iannaccone, they are charged in terms of sacrifice and stigma.2 Do you remember the Hare Krishnas? Shaved heads and saffron robes? Handing flowers to strangers along busy sidewalks and airport entries? No twice-a-year back-pewers there. Or how about the Jehovah Witnesses? Door-to-door evangelism and no blood transfusions. Ugh. Only the most committed adherents would pay such a price. Orthodox Jews with side curls and yarmulkes? Amish with no cars or electricity? Not easy to free-ride there either. Rest assured, members of these religious groups pay a very real price. When congregations impose prices like these, the uncommitted jump for safety. Free-riders vanish quickly. Sacrifice and stigma serve a second function as well. Not only do they keep free-riders out, they keep committed members in. Pepsi is a substitute for Coke. If Pepsi executives somehow could drive up the price of Coke, they could more easily lock in current customers. Pepsi buyers will not stray if Coke becomes more expensive. Similarly, secular activities are a substitute for the sacred. If a congregation can raise the price its members pay to participate in secular activities, they can more easily lock these members into sacred activities instead. Stigma and sacrifice fill the bill. In the words of Iannaccone: Distinctive diet, dress, grooming and social customs constrain and often stigmatize members, making participation in alternative activities more costly. Potential members are forced to choose: participate fully or not at all.3 Presbyterians can easily interact with the secular world and people of other faiths. The Amish cannot. Presbyterians can easily free ride. The Amish cannot. With free riders out of the game, strict churches enjoy more loyal participation and higher financial contributions per member.4 Iannaccone's sacrifice and stigma thesis also explains an intriguing paradox of church growth. Conventional wisdom would predict that making membership easy would increase a group's rate of growth. However, those faiths which demand the most sacrifice and stigma are among the fastest growing. For example, Mormons have enjoyed exponential growth, yet place heavy demands upon members. Anyone for a ten percent tithe and a two-year mission? Similarly, Pentecostalism has grown very rapidly despite, or because of, the high commitments of time, energy and money expected of its members. The Joy of Economics http://faculty.winthrop.edu/stonebrakerr/book/stigma.htm 3 of 5 5/3/17, 9:27 PM On the other hand, mainstream Protestant denominations place minimal demands upon members. No weird apparel. No bizarre customs. No onerous financial requirements. However, these are precisely the denominations which have been losing members and market share in recent decades. Membership is cheap, but so is free-riding. Have marginal members sapped the strength and fervor from such churches? In recent years megachurches have taken this message to heart and used it to their strategic advantage.5 Congregations such as Willow Creek Community Church and Saddleback Church, each with more than 20,000 weekly attendees, have been spectacularly successful in targeting "seekers" who may never have belonged to a church or who dropped away because of dissatisfaction with another religious organization. Because many of these seekers have been turned off by prior experiences, charging a high price might easily discourage them ever from trying out a new congregation. How then can such seekers be attracted? By cutting the price; at least initially. Just as the local fitness center or cable system might offer low introductory rates to attract new customers, the megachurches often charge a very low -- even zero -- initial price to visitors. For example, worship leaders at Saddleback explain that donations are not expected from non-members when the offering plates are passed. Visitors are allowed to "shop" in relative anonymity with little or no pressure to give or contribute. However, once the visitor feels that he or she has found a good religious fit and chooses to join the congregation, prices escalate rapidly. Members are expected to participate in small group ministries, to maintain faithful lifestyles, and to give generously of their time and money. Just as the low, introductory rate at the fitness center evaporates after a few months, so do the minimal expectations for attendee commitment. Different strokes for different folks Sacrifice and stigma are not foolproof strategies for enhancing church growth. Not all potential members will be persuaded, and not all current members will stay. After all, sacrificing secular alternatives is costly, at least for those with attractive secular alternatives. The types of alternatives available are critical. Who is more likely to toss a secular career in the can and join a commune in the woods: the middle-aged corporate leader with a six-figure salary and four children approaching college, or the unemployed teenager next door with no family to support? Costs and benefits still matter, and the cost of a religious commune life to the corporate leader dwarfs that paid by her teen-aged neighbor. The data agree.6 The strictest and most demanding religious groups do tend to attract those with the least attractive secular options: the less educated, the less well-to-do, the young, women and minorities. And these groups also experience cyclical swings. When the economy drops into a recession and unemployment rates rise, membership in strict religious groups also tends to rise. When the economy recovers and job opportunities improve, memberships in these same groups fall. What is the result? To discourage free-riders who might otherwise poison your groups' evangelical ardor, sacrifice and stigma make sense. But, if you want to attract the rich and famous, forget about a demanding theology and behavioral norms. Sacrifice and stigma are too costly for most to bear. Most will opt out for other, less demanding faiths. _________________________________________ Notes: Part of this reading was published in Robert J. Stonebraker, "Should Members be Required to Participate in The Joy of Economics http://faculty.winthrop.edu/stonebrakerr/book/stigma.htm 4 of 5 5/3/17, 9:27 PM Ministry," Episcopal Life, February 2003. 1. As the number of members in a congregation rises, the cost per member tends to fall. See Robert J. Stonebraker, "Optimal Church Size: The Bigger the Better?" Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, volume 32, number 3 (September 1993), pp. 231-241. 2. Laurence R. Iannaccone, "Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives," Journal of Political Economy, volume 100, number 2 (April 1992), pp. 271-291. 3. Ibid., page 276. 4. See Olson, Daniel V. A. and Perl, Paul, "Free and Cheap Riding in Strict Conservative Churches," Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, June 2005, volume 44, number 2, pp. 123-142. 5. This paragraph draws heavily on the analysis of Marc von der Ruhr and Joseph P. Daniels, "Examining Megachurch Growth: Free Riding, Fit and Faith", International Journal of Social Economics, 2012, volume 39, issue 5, pp. 342-356. 6. See Iannaccone, op. cit., pp. 283-289, for a review of the statistical evidence. _______________________________

Testing Yourself To test your understanding of the major concepts in this reading, try answering the following:

1. Explain the problem of free-riding in religious congregations.

2. Explain how sacrifice and stigma can counteract free-riding.

3. Explain how and why some megachurches adjust "prices" to attract members and still avoid free riding.

4. Describe the types of people most likely to join strict religious groups and explain

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image_2

Step: 3

blur-text-image_3

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Transdisciplinarity For Sustainability Aligning Diverse Practices

Authors: Martina Keitsch

1st Edition

0429581505, 9780429581502

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions

Question

=+i. Approximately 95% of the time, will be within _____ of m.

Answered: 1 week ago

Question

The role of life: It consists of your own service to yourself.

Answered: 1 week ago