1. What reasons did Leegin give for wanting the minimum price established for its retailers? 2. What...

Question:

1. What reasons did Leegin give for wanting the minimum price established for its retailers?

2. What points does the court make about not having minimum prices in terms of reducing competition?

3. What risks are there in allowing minimum price requirements?

Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc., designs, manufactures, and distributes leather goods and accessories under the brand name “Brighton.” The Brighton brand is sold across the United States in over 5,000 retail stores. PSKS, Inc., runs Kay’s Kloset, a Brighton retailer in Lewisville, Texas, that carries about 75 different product lines but was known as the place in that area to go for Brighton. Leegin’s president, Jerry Kohl, who also has an interest in about 70 stores that sell Brighton products, believes that small retailers treat customers better, provide customers more services, and make their shopping experience more satisfactory than do larger, often impersonal retailers. In 1997, Leegin instituted the “Brighton Retail Pricing and Promotion Policy,” which banished retailers that discounted Brighton goods below suggested prices.

In December 2002, Leegin discovered that Kay’s Kloset had been marking down Brighton’s entire line by 20 percent. When Kay’s would not stop marking the Brighton products prices down, Leegin stopped selling to the store.

PSKS sued Leegin for violation of the antitrust laws. The jury awarded PSKS $1.2 million in damages and the judge trebled the damages and reimbursed PSKS for its attorney’s fees and costs—for a judgment against Leegin of $3,975,000.80.

The Court of Appeals affirmed. Leegin appealed.

JUDICIAL OPINION

KENNEDY, Justice … In Dr. Miles Medical Co. v John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 31 S.Ct. 376, 55 L.Ed. 502 (1911), the Court established the rule that it is per se illegal under § 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, for a manufacturer to agree with its distributor to set the minimum price the distributor can charge for the manufacturer’s goods. The question presented by the instant case is whether the Court should overrule the per se rule and allow resale price maintenance agreements to be judged by the rule of reason, the usual standard applied to determine if there is a violation of § 1.

The Court has abandoned the rule of per se illegality for other vertical restraints a manufacturer imposes on its distributors. Respected economic analysts, furthermore, conclude that vertical price restraints can have procompetitive effects. We now hold that that vertical price restraints are to be judged by the rule of reason Section 1 of the Sherman Act.

The rule of reason is the accepted standard for testing whether a practice restrains trade in violation of § 1. The rule of reason does not govern all restraints. Some types “are deemed unlawful per se.” The per se rule, treating categories of restraints as necessarily illegal, eliminates the need to study the reasonableness of an individual restraint in light of the real market forces at work, and, it must be acknowledged, the per se rule can give clear guidance for certain conduct. Restraints that are per se unlawful include horizontal agreements among competitors to fix prices, or to divide markets.

… [T]he per se rule is appropriate only after courts have had considerable experience with the type of restraint at issue, and only if courts can predict with confidence that it would be invalidated in all or almost all instances under the rule of reason. [I]t is necessary to examine, in the first instance, the economic effects of vertical agreements to fix minimum resale prices, and to determine whether the per se rule is nonetheless appropriate.

The justifications for vertical price restraints are similar to those for other vertical restraints. Minimum resale price maintenance can stimulate interbrand competition—the competition among manufacturers selling different brands of the same type of product—by reducing intrabrand competition—the competition among retailers selling the same brand. The promotion of interbrand competition is important because “the primary purpose of the antitrust laws is to protect [this type of] competition.” A single manufacturer’s use of vertical price restraints tends to eliminate intrabrand price competition; this in turn encourages retailers to invest in tangible or intangible services or promotional efforts that aid the manufacturer’s position as against rival manufacturers. Resale price maintenance also has the potential to give consumers more options so that they can choose among low-price, low-service brands; high-price, high-service brands; and brands that fall in between…………………………….

Fantastic news! We've Found the answer you've been seeking!

Step by Step Answer:

Related Book For  book-img-for-question

Business Law Principles for Today's Commercial Environment

ISBN: 978-1305575158

5th edition

Authors: David P. Twomey, Marianne M. Jennings, Stephanie M Greene

Question Posted: