Question
Case study 1.1: Global Warming Part I: What to do about global warming A UN treaty now under discussion looks promising - as long as
Case study 1.1: Global Warming
Part I: What to do about global warming
A UN treaty now under discussion looks promising -
as long as it remains flexible
How should reasonable people react to the hype and
controversy over global warming? Judging by recent
headlines, you might think we are already doomed.
Newspapers have been quick to link extreme
weather events, ranging from floods in Britain and
Mozambique to hurricanes in Central America,
directly to global warming. Greens say that worse will
ensue if governments do not act. Many politicians
have duly jumped on the bandwagon, citing recent
disasters as a reason for speeding up action on the
Kyoto treaty on climate change that commits rich
countries to cut emissions of greenhouse gases. This
week saw the start of a summit in The Hague to
discuss all this.
Yet hot-headed attempts to link specific weather
disasters to the greenhouse effect are scientific bunk.
The correct approach is coolly to assess the science of
climate change before taking action. Unfortunately,
climate modelling is still in its infancy, and for most of
the past decade it has raised as many questions as it
has answered. Now, however, the picture is getting
clearer. There will never be consensus, but the
balance of the evidence suggests that global warming
is indeed happening; that much of it has recently
been man-made; and that there is a risk of potentially
disastrous consequences. Even the normally stolid
insurance industry is getting excited. Insurers reckon
that weather disasters have cost roughly $400 billion
over the past decade and that the damage is likely
only to increase. The time has come to accept that
global warming is a credible enough threat to require
a public-policy response.
But what, exactly? At first blush, the Kyoto treaty
seems to offer a good way forward. It is a global
treaty: it would be foolish to deal with this most
global of problems in any other way. It sets a longterm
framework that requires frequent updating and
revision, rather like the post-war process of trade
liberalisation. That is sensible because climate
change will be at least a 100-year problem, and so
will require a treaty with institutions and mechanisms
that endure. The big question over Kyoto remains its
cost. How much insurance is worth buying now
against an uncertain, but possibly devastating, future
threat? And the answer lies in a clear-headed
assessment of benefits and costs. The case for doing
something has increased during the three years since
Kyoto was signed. Yet it also remains true that all
answers will be easier if economic growth is
meanwhile sustained: stopping the world while the
problem is dealt with is not a sensible option, given
that resources to deal with it would then become
steadily scarcer.
That points to two general conclusions about how
to implement Kyoto. The simplest is that countries
should search out ''no regrets'' measures that are
beneficial in their own right as well as reducing
emissions - such as scrapping coal subsidies,
liberalising energy markets and cutting farm support.
The second is that implementation should use
market-friendly measures that minimise the costs
and risks of slowing economic growth.
Part II: Hot potato revisited
A lack-of-progress report on the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change
You might think that a policy issue which puts at stake
hundreds of billions of dollars' worth of global output
would arouse at least the casual interest of the
world's economics and finance ministries. You would
be wrong. Global warming and the actions
contemplated to mitigate it could well involve costs
of that order. Assessing the possible scale of future
greenhouse-gas emissions, and hence of man-made
global warming, involves economic forecasts and
economic calculations. Those forecasts and
calculations will in turn provide the basis for policy on
the issue. Yet governments have been content to
leave these questions to a body - the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
(IPCC) - which appears to lack the necessary
expertise. The result is all too likely to be bad policy, at
potentially heavy cost to the world economy.
In our Economics focus of February 15th this year,
we drew attention to (and posted on our website)
telling criticisms of the IPCC's work made by two
independent commentators, Ian Castles, a former
head of Australia's Bureau of Statistics, and David
Henderson, formerly the chief economist of the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) and now visiting professor at
Westminster Business School. Their criticisms of the
IPCC were wide-ranging, but focused on the panel's
forecasts of greenhouse-gas emissions. The method
employed, the critics argued, had given an upward
bias to the projections.
The IPCC's procedure relied, first, on measuring
gaps between incomes in poor countries and
incomes in rich countries, and, second, on supposing
that those gaps would be substantially narrowed, or
entirely closed, by the end of this century. Contrary to
standard practice, the IPCC measured the initial gaps
using market-based exchange rates rather than rates
adjusted for differences in purchasing power. This
error makes the initial income gaps seem far larger
than they really are, so the subsequent catching-up is
correspondingly faster. The developing-country
growth rates yielded by this method are historically
implausible, to put it mildly. The emissions forecasts
based on those implausibly high growth rates are
accordingly unsound.
The Castles-Henderson critique was subsequently
published in the journal Energy and Environment
(volume 14, number 2-3). A response by 15 authors
associated with the IPCC purporting to defend the
panel's projections was published in the same issue.
It accused the two critics of bias, bad faith, peddling
''deplorable misinformation'' and neglecting what the
15 regard as proper procedure. Alas, it fails to answer
the case Mr Castles and Mr Henderson had laid out -
namely, that the IPCC's low-case scenarios are
patently not low-case scenarios, and that the panel
has therefore failed to give a true account of the range
of possibilities. If anything, as the two critics argue in
an article in the subsequent issue of Energy and
Environment, the reply of the 15 authors gives new
grounds for concern. This week the IPCC is preparing
to embark on its next global-warming ''assessment
review'' - and if the tone of its reply to the critics is any
guide, it is intent on business as usual.
Nature, scope and methods 5
This case study illustrates the variety of issues with which managerial
economics is concerned. The following questions arise:
1. Is there a problem to be addressed?
2. Is there a solution or solutions to the problem, in terms of strategies or
courses of action that can be taken?
3. What objective or objectives can be defined for these strategies?
4. What constraints exist in terms of operating any strategies?
5. How can we identify strategies as solutions to the problem?
6. How can we evaluate these strategies in terms of costs and benefits, particularly
when these involve life and health?
7. What is the best way of measuring the relevant variables?
8. What assumptions should be made in our analysis?
9. How do we deal with the problem of risk and uncertainty regarding the
future and the effects of strategies in the future?
10. How can we approach the problems of conflicts of interest between different
countries and between different consumers and producers?
It is true, as the IPCC says in its defence, that the
panel presents a range of scenarios. But, as we
pointed out before, even the scenarios that give the
lowest cumulative emissions assume that incomes in
the developing countries will increase at a much
faster rate over the course of the century than they
have ever done before. Disaggregated projections
published by the IPCC say that - even in the lowestemission
scenarios - growth in poor countries will be
so fast that by the end of the century Americans will
be poorer on average than South Africans, Algerians,
Argentines, Libyans, Turks and North Koreans. Mr
Castles and Mr Henderson can hardly be alone in
finding that odd.
TUNNEL VISION
The fact that the IPCC mobilised as many as 15
authors to supply its response is interesting. The
panel's watchword is strength in numbers (lacking
though it may be in strength at numbers). The
exercise criticised by Mr Castles and Mr Henderson
involved 53 authors, plus 89 expert reviewers and
many others besides. Can so many experts get it
wrong? The experts themselves may doubt it, but the
answer is yes. The problem is that this horde of
authorities is drawn from a narrow professional
milieu. Economic and statistical expertise is not
among their strengths. Making matters worse, the
panel's approach lays great emphasis on peer review
of submissions. When the peers in question are
drawn from a restricted professional domain -
whereas the issues under consideration make
demands upon a wide range of professional skills -
peer review is not a way to assure the highest
standards of work by exposing research to scepticism.
It is just the opposite: a kind of intellectual restrictive
practice, which allows flawed or downright shoddy
work to acquire a standing it does not deserve.
Part of the remedy proposed by Mr Castles and Mr
Henderson in their new article is to get officials from
finance and economics ministries into the long-range
emissions-forecasting business. The Australian
Treasury is now starting to take an active interest in
IPCC-related issues, and a letter to the British
Treasury drawing attention to Castles-Henderson
(evidently it failed to notice unassisted) has just
received a positive, if long delayed, response. More
must be done, and soon. Work on a question of this
sort would sit well with Mr Henderson's former
employer, the OECD. The organisation's economic
policy committee - a panel of top economic officials
from national ministries - will next week install
Gregory Mankiw, head of America's Council of
Economic Advisers, as its new chairman. If Mr
Mankiw is asking himself what new work that body
ought to take on under his leadership, he need look
no further than the dangerous economic
incompetence of the IPCC.
6 INTRODUCTION
11 What criteria can we use for selecting strategies from among different
possible courses of action?
12 How do political biases and agendas affect decision-making processes in
practice?
The above questions represent steps in the decision-making process involved
not just in the global warming situation, but also in any situation involving
decision-making. However, many people are unaware of the breadth of issue
that is amenable to the analysis of managerial economics. In particular, they
sometimes regard managerial economists as being apologists for greedy capitalists,
who do not take quality of life into consideration, or the long-term interests
of the public. They may view markets with suspicion and doubt their ability to
allocate resources efficiently, for example the creation of trading rights in pollution.
They may fear deregulation, seeing it as leading to the exploitation of
consumers by monopolists. They may believe that it is impossible in principle
to put a money value on human life or health. Theymay believe that governments
should not be swayed by narroweconomic interests and analysis, and have a duty
to exercise ethical principles which otherwise would not be considered. Such
antagonistic feelings towards global capitalism have been expressed at various
meetings of international politicians to discuss world trade. On amore academic
level, there has for some years been huge controversy surrounding the publication
of a book by Lomborg3 taking an economist's approach to these issues.
Much of the sentiment expressed is based on an ignorance of the issues
involved, a misuse of statistical information and a lack of understanding of
economic analysis, its relevance and application. One major objective of this
book is to explain not just the methodology of managerial economics but also
the breadth of its application, and to illustrate that it can have a lot to say about
the types of issue raised in the above case study. All the case studies in the text
have been selected with this objective in mind; for example the following
situations and issues are discussed: prize money in sport, the law of diminishing
returns applied to computer software, Internet banking and competition,
price discrimination in the pharmaceutical industry, issues in the National
Health Service, deregulation of electrical utilities, the level of fuel taxes and
subsidized car manufacturing.
This is the case, please help me
Step by Step Solution
There are 3 Steps involved in it
Step: 1
Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions
See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success
Step: 2
Step: 3
Ace Your Homework with AI
Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance
Get Started