Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

...
1 Approved Answer

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at: https://www.emerald.com/insight/2515-8961.htm Institutional factors and Subnational location choice subnational location

image text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribedimage text in transcribed
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at: https://www.emerald.com/insight/2515-8961.htm Institutional factors and Subnational location choice subnational location choice for multinationals' R&D subsidiaries Christian Falaster 351 Graduate School of Management (PPGAd), Universidade Regional de Blumenau (FURB), Blumenau, Brazil, and Received 19 August 2019 Revised 27 November 2019 Manuel Portugal Ferreira Accepted 11 December 2019 School of Management and Technology, Instituto Politecnico de Leiria, Leiria, Portugal and Departamento de Administracao e Economia, Universidade Federal de Lavras, Lavras, Brazil Abstract Purpose - Using an institution-based view, this study aims to conceptualize how sub-national institutional characteristics are likely to explain location choice of multinationals' research and development (R&D) subsidiaries. Design/methodology/approach - In a conceptual paper, this study explores specific institutional facets of the regional environments within a country that are capable of explaining, at least in part, the location choices of multinational corporations' R&D subsidiaries. Findings - This study thus explores the more nuanced influences of the institutional environments at a subnational level and develops propositions to explain location choices based on the differences of the institutional environments. Originality/value - This study contributes to international business theory by incorporating a location- specific analysis that contrasts to the usual country-level observation on the determinants of firms' location decisions. Keywords Location choice, Regional differences, Institutional environment, Innovation Paper type Conceptual paper Introduction Research on innovation-driven multinational corporations (MNCs) has gained increasing significance in international business studies (Cano-Kollmann, Cantwell, Hannigan, Mudambi, & Song, 2016). This interest warrants more attention on the institutional settings where innovations are conducted. Especially, how MNCs explore and exploit their knowledge (March, Christian Falaster and Manuel Portugal Ferreira. Published in Innovation & Management Review. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) license. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this license may be seen at http:// creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode This study is part and received support from the project "906/2017 A incerteza inerente as Innovation & Management ineficiencyas institucionais e seus efeitos nas estrategias internacionais das organizacoes" by Review Universidade Regional de Blumenau. Vol. 17 No. 4, 2020 pp. 351-367 This study was financed in part by the Coordenacao de Aperfeicoamento de Pessoal de Nivel Emerald Publishing Limited 2515-8961 Superior - Brasil (CAPES) - Finance Code 001. DOI 10.1108/INMR-08-2019-0102INMR 1991) worldwide to acquire novel resources and learn (Tallman & Fladmoe-Lindquist, 2002; 17,4 Luo & Tung, 2007). That is, some locations have specific and largely idiosyncratic institutional settings that may be more prone to innovation than others (Mudambi, 2008). However, while we understand well that institutions develop differently across countries (Dikova & Van Witteloostuijn, 2007; Jackson & Deeg, 2008; Berry, Guillen, & Zhou, 2010) and that different countries have different national innovation systems (NIS) (Lundvall, 2007), we have but a poor 352 understanding of how the sub-national institutional differences (Mudambi, 2008; Chan, Makino, & Isobe, 2010; Ma, Delios, & Lau, 2013) determine MNCs' location choices, in particular regarding the location of research and development (R&D) subsidiaries. This line of enquiry is especially relevant given the foundational role of knowledge, learning and innovation for MNCs' competitive ability (Feinberg & Gupta, 2004). Institutional environments have become central to international business (IB) research Jackson & Deeg, 2019) because of a focus on an institution-based view (Peng, Wang, & Jiang, 2008). Some studies have investigated the effects of the institutional context on cross-border acquisitions (Pinto et al., 2017; Dow, Cuypers, & Ertug, 2016), subsidiary performance (Brannen, Piekkari & Tietze, 2014) and choice of location for foreign operations (Ma et al., 2013; Lu, Liu, Wright, & Filatotchev, 2014). Most of the existing institutional-based studies take on a country-level perspective (Meyer, 2001; Dikova & Van Witteloostuijn, 2007; Cuervo-Cazurra & Dau, 2009), that is, they consider nation-level institutions. However, a small stream of research has defended that countries are not homogeneous among their internal regions (Beugelsdijk & Mudambi, 2013) and that examining how subnational institutions may influence MNCs could bring important contributions to IB (Chan et al., 2010; Meyer & Nguyen, 2005). More specifically, themes such as subnational region variations (Dai, Eden, & Beamish, 2013), global cities (Goerzen, Asmussen, & Nielsen, 2013; Asmussen, Nielsen, Goerzen, & Tegtmeier, 2018) and microfoundations of spatial perception (Piscitello, 2011) have the potential to contribute to IB theory regarding how subnational institutional environments are capable of shaping location choice. In this article, we use an institutional based view and follow the studies that propose that differences across sub-national locations (cities, states, regions and countries) matter - because of pronounced differences in the economic, productive, cultural, social, historic, demographic, administrative and governmental backgrounds (North, 1990; Ghemawat, 2001; Berry et al., 2010). We analyze how these institutional differences across locations render differences in the innovativeness (or ability to innovate) and are thus likely to drive the locations selected by MNCs to locate their international R&D subsidiaries. Our purpose is thus to advance how the institutional and economic contexts are asymmetrical across regions within the same country, affecting innovativeness, to then point out conceptually driven propositions of how these asymmetries can affect subsidiary location choice. In sum, in this study, we propose that places (cities, states and regions) within a country have specific institutional contexts that are distinct, albeit probably dependent from the wider country-level institutional context. The evidences for our premise are abundant. First, historical and economic trajectories of a society shape the institutional context (North, 1990). The government regulatory laws, the very culture of the society and even the firms operating in a location can have an impact on the development of institutions (Faulconbridge & Muzio, 2015). Second, the different economic and social developments of a location will generate different institutional contexts across regions (Krugman, 1991; Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011; Andersson & Henrekson, 2014; Winters, 2013), and different coercive and normative pressures (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Even slightly different societies are likely to mean greater difficulty of gaining legitimacy (Suchman, 1995).This study has two main contributions to international business theory and research on innovation. First, we provide a perspective for researchers to analyze how the sub-national institutional variation will determine MNCs' location choice. That is, we gain additional insight into the location determinants using an institutional perspective that delves into the specicities, or variations, within a sub-national level. While the focus of attention on studies on location choice have mostly taken the country as the unit of analysis, research studies in international business and innovation are likely to gain from recognizing the sub- national institutional heterogeneity and how it matters for rms' decisions. A second contribution is directed to studies on innovation in an international perspective whereby rms expand to learn, augment their knowledgebased capabilities and acquire new ones. Often this stream of research relies on examining country-level differences and variations on knowledge and innovation are assessed in terms of differences between countries. These differences between countries are the outcome of differences in the cultural, economic, entrepreneurial, social, political, legal, geographic, demographic, etc. milieu (Berry et all, 2010; Ghemawat, 2001). Hence, some regions may be more institutionally sophisticated and more innovative than others. In other instances, scholars have delved into the difculties of learning across borders because of, for example, the liability of foreignness (Zaheer, 1995). We propose that by bringing together what we know about the national variations with additional knowledge on how the subnational idiosyncrasies matter, we come closer to understand how rms can leverage or augment their innovation capabilities across heterogeneous spaces. Literature review Although Dunning (1998) has perceived location as an underdeveloped and neglected aspect in international business, the eld has been receiving greater attention over the past decades. Mostly, this research has taken the national border, or the country, as the unit of analysis to understand decisions and actions of rms in such respects as location choice (Makino, Lau, & Yeh, 2002; Chung & Alcacer, 2002; Ramasamy, Yeung, & Laforet, 2012) and entry mode choice (Kogut & Singh, 1988; Dikova & Van Witteloostuijn, 2007; Mueller, Hendriks, & Slangen, 2017). The focus on the border as a central part of the analysis makes sense as most of the institutional constraints change rather drastically from country to country, resulting in a heterogeneity of environmental contexts in which rms operate. However, a complementary perspective has been emerging observing additional levels of heterogeneity at the subnational level. The special heterogeneity at the subnational level is a critical factor driving the actual location decisions by MNCs (Ma et all, 2013; Lu et all, 2014; Kim & Aguilera, 2016; Asmussen et (11., 2018). As pointed by Asmussen et a]. (2018) this stream of inquiry is still debating with clear guidelines on how to divide countries in more meaningful units and precision in establishing and measuring spatial differences. The characterization of locations has been more scrutinized in elds such as economic geography, urban planning, demography and even sociology, showing the opportunity of developing further works in IE studies. The extant research on MNCs' location choices has somewhat moved from the country to the regional or subnational level (Beugelsdijk, McCann, & Mudambi, 2010; Ma, Tong & Fitza, 2013; Chan et all, 2010). This has meant greater focus on economic geography and how rms tend to concentrate, or agglomerate, in some center, often large cities (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011) and global cities (Goerzen et all, 2013), as these are centers of economic activity. The duality of large and small cities is very visible in many countries and perhaps more remarkably in the emerging economies of Brazil, China and India, where such cities such as Sao Paulo, New Delhi, Shanghai and Mexico City are far larger than other Subnational location choice 353 INMR cities in the country (Ma & Delios, 2007). These cities are also often either capital cities, 17,4 political centers or economic hubs, financially more developed and broadly stated more institutionally developed than peripheral areas, and thus attractive to large populations. However, some researchers have called for the attention to considering the specific characteristics of the location where the subsidiary will operate (city or region) rather than just the effects of national borders (Dai et al., 2013; Goerzen et al., 2013; Piscitello, 2011). 354 Researchers usually calculate institutional distance from one country to another (Berry et al., 2010), regardless of where - in what region, or city - in the target country the subsidiary will be installed (Beugelsdijk & Mudambi, 2013). The basic assumption is that the national border effects (the country-level distances and characteristics) are important, but recent advancements show that the micro-level characteristics of the location, albeit often disregarded, should not be neglected (Beugelsdijk & Mudambi, 2013), especially in the case of sub-national institutional characteristics (Nguyen et al., 2013; Meyer & Nguyen, 2005). That is, while the more commonly studied nation-level effects are very important, more attention needs to be devoted to subnational effects on firms' strategies. Location and institutions It is essential to understand the institutional environments in international business Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Peng, Wang, & Jiang, 2008) and in innovation (Rasiah, 2017) as they influence firms' choices and strategies. Countries are essentially different in many aspects, possessing different cultures, laws, economies and ways of living and of doing business (North, 1990). The institutional settings have a strong impact on how firms will operate, as they need to deal with legislation, their competitors and the socially established expectations of what is required of them (DiMagio & Powell, 1983; Suchman, 1995). Hence, the set of institutions may sometimes have a greater impact on the choice of, for instance, foreign direct investment (FDI) location than economic-driven explanations (Kang & Jiang, 2012 ). As institutions are "the rules of the game in a society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction" (North, 1990, p. 3), firms need to take into account the institutional constraints, inefficiencies and particularities of a country in the decisions regarding internationalization (Chan & Makino, 2007), such as location (Nguyen et al., 2013). The diversity of institutional frameworks presents a major challenge for firms operating across countries and locations. Some countries have so little in common that they may present major economic disparities, such as different types of capitalism (Jackson & Deeg, 2008) and the cultural setting that determines the interpersonal relations as, for instance, the behavior of executives (Lau, Tse, & Zhou, 2002). Because of institutional inefficiencies, many constraints rise to the concerns of firms. Formal institutional inefficiencies such as poor property rights, contract enforcement and flawed regulatory structures (Khanna & Palepu, 2000) will raise uncertainty in contracts between firms. Under conditions of contractual uncertainty, the costs of transacting increase (e.g. the costs of procuring operations and resources outside of the firms' boundaries), and it becomes more complex to adapt the firms' governance to the institutional characteristics of the location (Roth & Kostova, 2003). Another level of complexity is added when we take into account that institutions are likely to vary remarkably across the sub-regions of a country, and that governments have different levels of efficiency in different regions (Pearce & Ayres, 2009). Countries have different settings regarding innovation incentives and support, which result in different innovativeness environments, largely because of different NIS (Lundvall, 1992; Freeman, 2002). NIS are formed by public policies and firms' initiatives that guide and support innovation efforts in a country (Nelson, 1993; Lundvall, 2007). Research regarding NIS has gone hand in handwith policymaking in countries since its beginnings (Lundvall, 2007). Historically, international Subnational competitiveness has studied the innovativeness of a nation as a factor (Mowery & Oxley, 1995). location choice Subnational location choice for research and development subsidiaries The location choice for R&D subsidiaries has been a topic of interest for researchers. More specifically, Demirbag & Glaister (2010) analyzed differences between emerging and developed regions; Siedschlag, Smith, Turcu, & Zhang (2013) conducted a study to analyze 355 country-level determinants for location choice; Alcacer, Dezso, & Zhao (2013) analyzed the positioning of R&D subsidiaries in relation to global value chains; and Feinberg & Gupta (2004) analyzed how the R&D subsidiary decisions would influence spillovers. Meanwhile, the sub-national level of research still warrants attentions, especially as institutional factors can be specific to sub-national regions (Dietz, 2004) and may influence location choice decisions. The institutional differences between locations at a subnational level - or within the country - influence, and are a consequence, of such factors as innovation (Freeman, 2002), local government efficiency (Pearce & Ayres, 2009) and sub-national culture (Dietz, 2004). Even some developed countries have large differences in wages, labor force participation and employment across places in their territory (Winters, 2013). For instance, some places are historically and culturally more prone to entrepreneurship (Andersson & Henrekson, 2014) than others and thus sprawling a higher concentration of firms and consequently human capital. The differences in employment, labor force participation and wages are largely determined by the concentration of human capital, which acts as a positive externality because of intellectual spillovers (Winters, 2013). Although broadly debated, the innovation system can be different depending on the region within the country, not being homogeneous in the whole territory (Cooke, Uranga, & Etxebarria, 1997). Countries that, for instance, have different state-laws can have laws that benefit innovation in one state (such as better enforcement of the intellectual property rights) that do not exist in other states. These evidences point out that the innovation system(s) is not uniquely determined by the borders of a country, but can interchange and differ inside the country and throughout economic industries. We propose that firms observe the regional aspects just as national aspects when deciding the location of an international subsidiary. Regions have different institutional features regarding innovation, especially policymaking and normative procedures that can be different among regions from the same country supporting innovation initiatives, talent formation and attraction (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011). On the other hand, firms will avoid institutional environments that pose threats to their operations through high criminality, low rule of law and low protection of property rights, labeling these environments as "weak" institutional contexts (Khanna & Palepu, 2000). In essence, firms will choose subnational contexts that are more suitable for their operations (Beugelsdijk & Mudambi, 2013) and this is also observable at the sub-national level: P1. MNCs are likely to search for locations that have institutional environments that will support R&D and will not hinder their operations to locate their R&D subsidiaries. P2. The location of MNCs R&D subsidiaries varies across regions (states and cities) within a host country. Albeit there is an obvious variation in the location choice at a subnational level of MNCs R&D subsidiaries, there may be additional influences on the location choice in virtue of theINMR 17,4 356 degree of development of the country's institutional environment. That is, it is reasonable to expect that the patterns of location choices vary between emerging and developed countries. We specically argue that in emerging economies, the location choices vary less than in more developed countries. That is because the institutional development (economic, cultural, education, health, etc.) across the subnational space varies more in emerging economies than in developed countries. That way, there are limited sub-national regions suitable for being chosen in emerging economies in comparison to developed economies. In addition, in emerging economies, there is greater uncertainty regarding industrial policy and frequent changes in rules and regulations (Meyer & Nguyen, 2005; Falaster & Ferreira, 2018) that emerge from the pro-market reforms that are being implemented (Cuervo-Cazurra, & Dau, 2009). Often these reforms are unevenly distributed across subnational regions. Moreover, in some instances, there is some degree of decentralization to the state and regional governments that prioritize different policy objectives. In sum, the wide institutional variations found in the less institutionally developed emerging economies is likely to lead MNCs to prefer locating in a few selected sites, possibly large cities and/or states that have made more substantial pro-market reforms. In contrast, the lower variations in more developed countries allows rms to be less inuenced by subnational variations and thus be able to locate more dispersed across the subnational regions: P3. The location of MNCs' R&D subsidiaries is more concentrated at the subnational level in emerging economies than in developed countries. Centers andpm'phm'es The subnational location differences may be rather pronounced such as is the case when contrasting centers and peripheries in most countries. Economic centers are typically more populated, culturally more active and economically more vibrant (Krugman, 1991). For instance, Sao Paulo, in Brazil, and Mexico City, in Mexico, are two of the most populated cities in the world since the 1900s, and are economic, technological, cultural, social and political centers to their nations. These centers contrast sharply with other peripheries, such as the region of the Amazon rainforest and the Chihuahuan desert, that are for the most part, unpopulated and economically unexpressive. Economic Centers are the result of the concentration of people, rms and resources (McCann, 1995). These centers are generally large cities that combine scale and urban benets (as well as liabilities) that are characteristic to these cities (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011). Urban development is the main reason for locations to become centers or peripheries (Krugman, 1991). The population concentrates in cities because of the urban externalities and benets. The urban centers tend to grow based on the consumption potential that they generate, thus attracting rms to explore the concentration (McCann, 1995; Glaeser, Kolko, & Saiz, 2001) but also because of the proximity to human resources, other rms and political agents. As economic centers will have more vibrant and recurrent economic activities, rms located in these economic centers will have to develop institutions to reduce uncertainties in their interactions (North, 1990). We thus propose that the increased interactions that centers provide will develop institutional environments that have industrial standards of cognitive legitimacy (because of the amount of interactions that happen there) (Suchman, 1995). The development of a workforce in the location because of information spillovers and the development of specic skills (Krugman, 1991) will help establish high standards for the operations of rms. These industrial standards will likely also become regulations either government or industry regulatory powers, which will increase normative and/or coercive pressures (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) into the rms operating in these centers to obtain legitimacy (Suchman, 1995). Hence, suppliers will abide by higher industry standards and universities will form professionals that can work in these higher standard industries. Higher standards of quality in operation of R&D will positively inuence regional innovativeness, which will contribute to the operations of R&D subsidiaries: P4. lVlNCs are likely to search for locations that are centers or close to centers political and economic centers to locate their R&D subsidiaries. Under conditions of greater institutional inefciencies, rms may need to develop distinct courses of action. For instance, rms may need to develop business groups to overcome local institutional voids (Khanna & Palepu, 2000), or nurture ties to the government and governmental agencies (Pinto et a1, 2017). Ties to the host location government help secure resources (Ma & Delios, 2010) or discretionary government intervention, for instance, regarding foreign ownership (Ma et a1, 2013). The extent of political intervention may vary across locations. For instance, Ma et (ll. (2013) noted how the location of central government agencies and the political apparatus in Beijing, compared to Shanghai, made Beijing more likely to have higher levels of political intervention requiring rms to be better politically connected. Similar situation may be observed, for instance, in Brazil, where the central government is located in Brasilia albeit Sao Paulo is economically more active, and the northeastern states being much less developed, and having less effective state and municipal level interference and control. A political center will concentrate political power in a country. At the same time, rms may resort to political connections to reduce institutional inefciencies found especially in emerging markets. R&D subsidiaries may benet, even more than other types of subsidiaries, from political connections reducing institutional inefciencies because of their need for safeguarding intellectual property rights (Maurer & Zugelder, 2000). Hence, rms will locate their R&D subsidiaries closer to political centers to ease the access to political connections and hence use them to safeguard their intellectual property against misappropriation: P5. In emerging economies, MNCs are likely to search for locations that are politically connected centers to locate their R&D subsidiaries. The microfoundations of economic differences between locations can be traced to historical antecedents. The rate of entrepreneurship in a location is path-dependent and can be rooted to a random historical event or a natural asset (Andersson & Larsson, 2016). Firms will prefer to co-locate because of information spillovers and the supply of industry-specic skilled workers (Krugman, 1991), which will generate specialized human capital because of the development of the agglomeration (Winters, 2013). Human capital will attract rms and the agglomeration will grow until the costs of agglomeration overcome the benets (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011). Public policy also plays a role in the creation of agglomerations, as policymakers develop incentives to attract \"talents\" and lure industrial facilities (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011). The agglomeration of rms holds some advantages (Porter, 1998), and these advantages make some agglomerations better for the location of MNCs' subsidiaries choice than others. Previous research has proven that agglomerations can reduce liabilities of foreignness and also bring potential knowledge spillovers (Lamin & Livanis, 2013). The concentration of rms from the same industry in a location offers more employment possibilities to workers with industry-specic skills; this concentration can also support the production of specialized inputs that are not tradable, and the possible information spillovers in the Subnational location choice 357 INMR 17,4 358 location can increase the performance of co-located rms (Krugman, 1991). The concentration of rms will produce an environment that leverages the human capital because of intellectual spillovers (Winters, 2013). Because of the potential advantages of agglomerating, agglomerations may seem a natural choice for R&D subsidiary location [although Pouder & John (1996) have argued that only some kinds of rms prefer agglomerations]. R&D subsidiaries will choose to locate in regions where they can have access to human resources that meet their standards. Locating in agglomerations could help R&D subsidiaries to benet from local technology spillovers and qualied human resources: P6. lVlNCs are likely to search for locations that have agglomerations of rms to locate their R&D subsidiaries. Culture The local culture and how local and corporate cultures differ are major inuencers of knowledge ows across and within rms. Larger cultural differences increase the uncertainty and complexity faced by managers that need to coordinate and integrate business practices and knowledge transfers (Ma et (ll, 2013). Local cultural idiosyncrasies are also likely to inuence location decisions. For example, Ma et a1. (2013, p. 956) noted that foreign MN Cs may seek to avoid locations in China where \"China's administrative styles or cultural values\" are more prominent. Ma et (ll. (2013) further noted how cities in China may differ. For instance, Beijing is considered as an administrative-cultural city with a dominant literati and bureaucrats given the concentration of the political systems of the country. In comparison, Shanghai has more of an entrepreneurial and managerial class. Similar comparisons may be made in other countries (F ujita & Hu, 2001). In Brazil, for instance, the entrepreneurial and economic activity of Sao Paulo contrasts sharply with the political-bureaucrats of Brasilia (the capital), where the central government and a large array of governmental agencies reside. While in Rio de Janeiro the entertainment and tourism industries are largely signicant, Florianopolis has a similar landscape but presents a far more innovation and creativity-driven economic activity (V asconcellos, Garrido, & Parente, 2019). The innovativeness of a location is inuenced by its culture. Mueller & Thomas (2001), for instance, have suggested that countries with low uncertainty avoidance (Hofstede, 1984) tend to have more innovative entrepreneurs than countries ranking high in uncertainty avoidance. Lower uncertainty avoidance may help ourish innovative behavior, acceptance and creativity. Hence, locations that have cultures more prone to innovation will nourish an environment that may foster innovation, through the development of government incentives, innovation-driven human resources and acceptance of novel ideas. We thus propose that rms will choose locations within a country to locate their R&D subsidiaries where there is a culture that values and supports innovation: P7. MNCs are likely to search for locations that have cultural traits that support and value innovation to locate their R&D subsidiaries. Locations within a country differ in terms of institutional structure, language, religion, education and culture. These differences are clearly observable between the more urban and the more rural areas, but they are also visible across urbanized areas in large countries such as Mexico or India, for instance. In fact, the urban locations in the emerging countries tend to resemble those in the developed countries with a more afuent and internationally mobile class (F ujita & Hu, 2001). The subnational variation in emerging countries also tends to be more diverse than in developed countries. Chan et a]. (2010) have noted the cultural and ethnical diversity across China and Russia, but similar evidence may be found in other emerging economies such as in Brazil or India. In Brazil, for instance, the northeastern states have a deep inuence of African religions in their culture. This is because of the large incidence of slavery in the northeastern states of Brazil throughout its history, resulting in an idiosyncratic mixture of cultures in those states. Meanwhile, the southern-most states have heavy protestant inuences brought by German immigration. In contrast, the more developed countries of Europe, or Eastern Europe, tend to have lower ethnical diversity because of their older history and geographical proximity. These subnational differences are likely to inuence the location of MNCs' R&D subsidiaries insofar as they affect a myriad of aspects relating to work, work ethics, interpersonal ties and organization. In some respects, some locations may even require the MNCs to rethink their operating model. For instance, the cultural and infrastructural features of a location may render that different models of distribution are more effective. For instance, when T-Systems, a branch of the German Deutsche Telekom, located an R&D subsidiary in Brazil, they chose Blumenau, a city founded by German immigrants that has received cultural inuences from many different ethnicities through immigration. This decision resulted in a more globally oriented mindset in the subsidiary, with German cultural inuences that make it more adapted to the corporative culture than their other subsidiaries located in countries like India. That is, rms need to adjust their location strategies according to the specicities of the locations, as replicating successful models abroad may not sufce. Embeddedness in the social fabric may be essential to learn in such environments. In sum, the cultural, social, ethnic and religious diversity found in less institutionally developed emerging economies drives MNCs to concentrate in a few selected locations, while the greater homogeneity found in the more developed countries allows for greater dispersion of where the subsidiaries are located at the subnational level: P8. The location of MNCs' R&D subsidiaries is more concentrated in the culturally diverse subnational level in emerging economies than in developed countries. [WM/Licking competitors Firms seek local institutional legitimacy in their international operations (Meyer et all, 2014). Hence, they need to abide to the actions expected by the social actors to achieve legitimacy (Suchman, 1995). One of the major alternatives for rms to achieve legitimacy is to engage in isomorphic behavior (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Deephouse, 1996). Researchers have pointed some strategic choices that contribute to rm legitimacy. Firms engage in isomorphic behavior looking to become more legitimate (Deephouse, 1996), and will have strategic responses to institutional change, seeking legitimacy. Hence, rms will mimic their more legitimate competitors or engage in strategic alliances to secure legitimacy by associating with rms that are considered more legitimate (Deephouse, 1996). All rms are susceptible to the institutional pressures that may arise from their environment, which may lead to three kinds of isomorphism: mimetic (mimicking, or imitating successful rms in search of success and legitimacy), coercive (bending through legislation pressures) and normative (professional norms and lore of doing things) (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Firms need to cope with these pressures to deal with their environment and operate properly, often engaging in isomorphic behavior (Hillman & Wan, 2005). This isomorphic behavior is higher in contexts where the institutional environment is very different from the one in the home-country, and lower where the environment is more similar with the home- Subnational location choice 359 INMR 17,4 360 country (Salomon & Wu, 2012). Evidences suggest that isomorphism can take decisive roles in the behavior of rms engaging in international business, commanding entry modes (Lu, 2002), nancial decisions (Henisz, 2003) and legitimacy-seeking behavior (Meyer et at, 2014). We thus propose that the isomorphic pressures that rms experience when internationalizing have an effect over the location choice of the R&D subsidiaries. For instance, a new technology rm entering the USA will probably prefer locating its R&D subsidiary in the Silicon Valley area. By selecting this location, the subsidiary benets from the spillovers of technology and human capital, but also gains added status and legitimacy because of the region being a common location choice for R&D rms. That is because the Silicon Valley will be perceived as more legitimate in their industry than in other locations in the country. That is, our argument is that MNCs' R&D subsidiaries will tend to co-locate because of mimetic and normative isomorphism, in search of legitimacy: P9. lVlNCs are likely to search for locations that that are common to rms in their industries because of isomorphic pressures to locate their R&D subsidiaries. Multinational corporations' strategies In addition to the MNCs' ability to manage the location's institutional idiosyncrasies, the location choice for the subsidiaries is likely to be inuenced by the strategy pursued and the role of the subsidiary in the lVlNCs network. That is, MNCs that follow a global strategy are likely to be driven more by location choices that favor lower costs and greater standardization. MNCs that pursue a learning strategy in a given market are likely to select locations that are richer in knowledge (Luo & Tung, 2007), and where the institutional milieu favors the learning and transfer of novel knowledge. Hence, the location choice for the R&D subsidiaries is likely the outcome of the interplay between the institutional characteristics of the location and the strategy pursued, or the strategic role sought for the subsidiary (Ma et al., 2013). Firms will choose locations that favor knowledge transfer when engaging in knowledge- seeking strategies (Kedia, Gaffney, & Clampit, 2012). Meanwhile, they will avoid locations that may induce knowledge transfer and spillovers when they do not see benets that may come from sharing knowledge. Benets of spillovers may be small for rms that already possess knowledge advantages and spillovers may even be detrimental if competitors could benet from spillovers of the rms' knowledge (Pouder & John, 1996). Hence, if a rm pursues a knowledge-seeking strategy, it will more likely choose locations where the institutional environment will nourish knowledge transfer, while if a rm pursues a global strategy, it may choose locations that protect their knowledge and reduce their costs. We propose: P10. MNCs are likely to search for locations that allow knowledge transfer when pursuing a knowledge-seeking strategy, and will avoid these locations if pursuing global strategies. Discussion and concluding remarks In this article, we discussed several factors to illustrate how we may examine subnational, or intra-country, location choices. Specically, we have delved into the location of R&D subsidiaries albeit similar reasoning could be used to enquire into the location of other types of subsidiaries. By analyzing the aspects that MNCs seek when locating their R&D subsidiaries, we develop knowledge regarding regional institutional environment, regional innovation environment and economic geography, linking these issues to propose an integrated logic regarding location-choice. We have advanced ten propositions to explain how locational institutional differences will determine international R&D subsidiary location choice at a subnational level. The main motivation for this study is the call from Beugelsdijk & Mudambi (2013) for a more detailed explanation of the differences between locations of the same country and their impact on location choice. Most studies, for instance Dow et ul. (2016), Brannen et ul. (2014) and Lu et ul. (2014), have observed the effects of country-level factors in performance and location choice of rms. We contribute to international business theory by providing a series of explanations that together may explain why rms will pick one location over the other for their R&D subsidiaries. Our study brings a perspective for researchers to interpret factors that make rms decide for one location over the other. Past research has greatly debated the cluster effects over international subsidiaries (Lamin & Livanis, 2013). However, differences in geographic centrality, institutional factors and innovativeness of the location are still very understudied topics. Our study suggests that rms will not only choose a location based on one factor or another but on a construct of four factors, i.e. geographic, economic, institutional and innovational. Hence, we expect this paper to assist researchers to observe inner-country location choice in an integrative perspective rather than an isolationist one. Our main contribution is the use of institutional theory in a sense of locational analysis. Although not completely novel, the locational perspective of institutional environment is an understudied topic in IE theory. Our paper contributes by proposing that local institutions do matter because they will shape the innovativeness of the location, along with locational norms and regulations that will make them more suitable to international R&D subsidiaries. Our propositions call for a more nuanced approach when analyzing location-choice decisions, by allowing an analysis that goes beyond the usual countryborder approach and considers regional characteristics. In a broader sense, our paper indicates that rms take into consideration country-level characteristics when deciding location; however, the specic regional characteristics may be more important in this decision, especially in the case of R&D subsidiaries. The second contribution of this paper is, in some extent, an explanation of why some locations are much more prone to receive innovation subsidiaries than others. For instance, locations such as the region of Guangdong in China, Grenoble-Isere in France and the Sillicon Valley in the USA, are reference in regard to innovative ability. We propose that these regions are innovative largely because of an array of institutional setting and cultural antecedents that sparked regulations and universities that fostered innovation, becoming centers and attracting additional rms. Future research avenues Certainly, the various institutional facets that characterize sub-national locations (regions or even cities) are prone to be highly intertwined. For instance, geographic determinants will inuence economic factors (Krugman, 1991). These economic factors will determine if the industries in that region are abundant and developed (Winters, 2013). Regions with an abundance of rms in an industry will have industry standards developed by the industry itself, as well as government regulations developed by governments concerned with these rms. Hence, the institutional environments will be different. Therefore, to gain an even clearer grasp on how each specic and individual institutional facet may drive location selection decision, more research is warranted to isolate each institutional dimension. For instance, rms may locate to some regions because they have specic laws fostering their Subnational location choice 361 INMR activity or may even avoid some regions because of high industry standards they cannot (or 17,4 rather do not want to) abide to. By analyzing R&D location choice in a sub-national level, it is possible to develop an understanding of how the distribution of knowledge assets can influence the economy, especially in emerging markets. If a country is mostly underdeveloped, it should not be an inviting destination for R&D subsidiaries; however, a country that is mostly 362 underdeveloped but manages to develop a single location where the conditions are prone to investments (as a regional R&D cluster) could become an inviting destination in that region. Hence, governments can put up public policies that seek to develop some specific locations in their territory to foster innovation initiatives and attract this kind of FDI, increasing economic benefits and technological spillovers that may be beneficial for the whole country. Studies can use quantitative methods to analyze the impacts of clusters and degrees of institutional characteristics in phenomena as FDI and location choice in a subnational level. Meanwhile, the topic warrants attention in a qualitative sense as the process for decision- making on the subnational location choice could benefit greatly from additional works using our framework. Location choice is an issue that has lined international business studies for the past decades (Kim & Aguilera, 2016). Although highly important, location had been an underdeveloped area in IB (Dunning, 1998). We follow Beugelsdijk & Mudambi (2013) and highlight the importance of not looking only at border factors, but also inner-border factors. This is a bridge from economic geography to international business that is highly understudied and deserves attention from both areas. Future research could contribute to both theories by analyzing how specific factors in geography determine location choice. For instance, firms that choose to locate to a region previously not common to firms in that industry probably resorted to geographic factors to choose that region. Issues such as travel time (Boeh & Beamish, 2012), centrality (Krugman, 1991), historical (Combes, Duranton & Gobillon, 2011) and even cultural ties to the home country may be roots to explanations that could make within-country location choice clearer. Strategies drive firms to locations (Lamin & Livanis, 2013). Although most research treat location choice as a matter of strategic decision (Alcacer, Dezso, & Zhao, 2013), the characteristics of firm or subsidiary also have influences on location choice. For instance, Doh, Bunyaratavej, & Hahn (2009) proposed that location choice will be different for different types of offshoring services (interactive, repetitive or innovative). Location choice not only acts as strategy but also has consequences for firms, as depending on the location and firm characteristics, firms may use different entry modes (Agarwal & Ramaswami, 1992). One of the most important aspects for future research in subnational differences could be linked to the analysis of the inter-relationships of the subnational characteristics. Research could benefit greatly from empirical tests that show how firms would behave when facing possibilities regarding regions that have associations of characteristics. More specifically, the questions of how these interactions between characteristics would influence firms could help researchers to better understand interactions between institutional characteristics and strategy (as proposed by Jackson & Deeg, 2019) at a subnational level. Moreover, research on tradeoffs between characteristics in location choice could benefit from our model. Within-country location choice is a topic that is still understudied in international business and should receive more attention. Differences among regions are because of several factors and all these factors contribute to a different outcome in location choice. It isimportant for researchers to not only consider border effects when studying location choice, Subnational but also the regional effects, as these seem to be highly neglected in literature. Country and location choice border effects are very important, but we suggest that regional effects must also be taken on account. The use of region-level data could bring some important contributions to international business both in theory and in empirical tests, as independent and control variables. 363 References Agarwal, S., & Ramaswami, S. N. (1992). Choice of foreign market entry mode: Impact of ownership, location and internalization factors. Journal of International Business Studies, 23(1), 1-27. Alcacer, J., Dezso, C., & Zhao, M. (2013). Firm rivalry, knowledge accumulation, and MNE location choices. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(5), 504-520. https://doi.org/10.1057/ jibs.2013.18 Andersson, M., & Henrekson, M. (2014). Local competitiveness fostered through local institutions for entrepreneurship. In Audretsch, D., Link, A., & Walshok, M., (Eds), Oxford handbook of local competitiveness, Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press. Andersson, M., & Larsson, J. (2016). Local entrepreneurship clusters in cities. Journal of Economic Geography, 16(1), 39-66. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbu049 Asmussen, C., Nielsen, B., Goerzen, A., & Tegtmeier, S. (2018). Global cities, ownership structures, and location choice: foreign subsidiaries as bridgeheads. Competitiveness Review: An International Business Journal, 28(3). https://doi.org/10.1108/CR-09-2017-0063 Berry, H., Guillen, M., & Zhou, N. (2010). An institutional approach to cross-national distance. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(9), 1460-1480. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2010.28 Beugelsdijk, S., & Mudambi, R. (2013). MNEs as border-crossing multi-location enterprises: The role of discontinuities in geographic space. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(5), 413-426. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2013.23 Beugelsdijk, S., Mccann, P., & Mudambi, R. (2010). Place, space and organization: Economic geography and the multinational enterprise. Journal of Economic Geography, 10(4), 485 493. https://doi.org/ 10.1093/jeg/1bq018 Boeh, K., & Beamish, P. (2012). Travel time and the liability of distance in foreign direct investment: Location choice and entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 43(5), 525-535. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2012.10 Brannen, M., Piekkari, R., & Tietze, S. (2014). The multifaceted role of language in international business: Unpacking the forms, functions and features of a critical challenge to MNC theory and performance. Journal of International Business Studies, 45(5), 495-507. https://doi.org/10.1057/ jibs.2014.24 Cano-Kollmann, M., Cantwell, J., Hannigan, T., Mudambi, R., & Song, J. (2016). Knowledge connectivity: An agenda for innovation research in international business. Journal of International Business Studies, 47(3), 255-262. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2016.8 Chan, C., & Makino, S. (2007). Legitimacy and multi-level institutional environments: Implications for oreign subsidiary ownership structure. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4), 621-638. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400283 Chan, C., Makino, S., & Isobe, T. (2010). Does subnational region matter? Foreign affiliate performance in the United States and China. Strategic Management Journal, 31(11), 1226-1243. https://doi. org/10.1002/smj.854 Chung, W., & Alcacer, J. (2002). Knowledge seeking and location choice of foreign direct investment in the United States. Management Science, 48(12), 1534-1554. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.12.1534.440INMR Combes, P., Duranton, G., & Gobillon, L. (2011). The identification of agglomeration economies. Journal 17,4 of Economic Geography, 11(2), 253-266. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/1bq038 Cooke, P., Uranga, M., & Etxebarria, G. (1997). Regional innovation systems: Institutional and organisational dimensions. Research Policy, 26(4/5), 475-491. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333 (97)00025-5 Cuervo-Cazurra, A., & Dau, L. A. (2009). Promarket reforms and firm profitability in developing countries. 364 Academy of Management Journal, 52(6), 1348-1368. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2009.47085192 Dai, L., Eden, L., & Beamish, P. (2013). Place, space, and geographical exposure: Foreign subsidiary survival in conflict zones. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(6), 554-578. https://doi. org/10.1057/jibs.2013.12 Deephouse, D. (1996). Does isomorphism legitimate?. Academy of Management Journal, 39(4), 1024-1039. https://doi.org/10.2307/256722 Demirbag, M., & Glaister, K. W. (2010). Factors determining offshore location choice for R&D projects: A comparative study of developed and emerging regions. Journal of Management Studies, 47(8), 1534-1560. Dietz, G. (2004). Frontier hybridisation or culture clash? Transnational migrant communities and Sub- national identity politics in Andalusia. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 30(6), 1087-1112. https://doi.org/10.1080/1369183042000286269 Dikova, D., & Van Witteloostuijn, A. (2007). Foreign direct investment mode choice: Entry and establishment modes in transition economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(6), 1013-1033. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400297 DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147-160. https://doi.org/ 10.2307/2095101 Doh, J. P., Bunyaratavej, K., & Hahn, E. D. (2009). Separable but not equal: The location determinants of discrete services offshoring activities. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(6), 926-943. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2008.89 Dow, D., Cuypers, I., & Ertug, G. (2016). The effects of within-country linguistic and religious diversity on foreign acquisitions. Journal of International Business Studies, 47(3), 319-346. https://doi.org/ 10.1057/jibs.2016.7 Dunning, J. H. (1998). Location and the multinational enterprise: A neglected factor?. Journal of International Business Studies, 29(1), 45-66. Falaster, C., & Ferreira, M. P. (2018). How generalized and arbitrary institutional inefficiencies shape equity in acquisitions. Academy of management proceedings, Briarcliff Manor, New York, NY: Academy of Management. (Vol. 2018, No. 1, p. 15210). Faulconbridge, J., & Muzio, D. (2015). Transnational corporations shaping institutional change: The case of English law firms in Germany. Journal of Economic Geography, 15(6), 1195-1226. https:// doi.org/10.1093/jeg/Ibu038 Feinberg, S., & Gupta, A. (2004). Knowledge spillovers and the assignment of R&D responsibilities to foreign subsidiaries. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8-9), 823-845. Freeman, C. (2002). Continental, national and sub-national innovation systems - complementarity and economic growth. Research Policy, 31(2), 191-211. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00136-6 Fujita, M., & Hu, D. (2001). Regional disparity in China, 1985-1994: the effects of globalization and economic liberalization. The Annals of Regional Science, 35(1), 3-37. https://doi.org/10.1007/ $001680000020 Ghemawat, P. (2001). Distance still matters. Harvard Business Review, 79(8), 137-147. Glaeser, E., Kolko, J., & Saiz, A. (2001). Consumer city. Journal of Economic Geography, 1(1), 27-50. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/1.1.27Goerzen, A., Asmussen, C., & Nielsen, B. (2013). Global cities and multinational enterprise location Subnational strategy. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(5), 427-450. https://doi.org/10.1057/ ibs.2013.11 location choice Henisz, W. (2003). The power of the Buckley and Casson thesis: The ability to manage institutional diosyncrasies. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(2), 173-184. https://doi.org/10.1057/ palgrave.jibs.8400015 Hillman, A., & Wan, W. (2005). The determinants of MNE subsidiaries' political strategies: Evidence of 365 institutional duality. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(3), 322-340. https://doi.org/ 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400137 Hofstede, G. (1984). Culture's consequences: International differences in work-related values, Sage, London. Jackson, G., & Deeg, R. (2008). Comparing capitalisms: Understanding institutional diversity and its implications for international business. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(4), 540-561. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400375 Jackson, G., & Deeg, R. (2019). Comparing capitalisms and taking institutional context seriously. Journal of International Business Studies, 50(1), 4-19. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-018- 0206-0 Kang, Y., & Jiang, F. (2012). FDI location choice of Chinese multinationals in East and Southeast Asia: Traditional economic factors and institutional perspective. Journal of World Business, 47(1), 5-53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2010.10.019 Kedia, B., Gaffney, N., & Clampit, J. (2012). EMNEs and knowledge-seeking FDI. Management International Review, 52(2), 155-173. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11575-012-0132-5 Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. (2000). Is group affiliation profitable in emerging markets? An analysis of diversified Indian business groups. The Journal of Finance, 55(2), 867-891. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/0022-1082.00229 Kim, J. U., & Aguilera, R. V. (2016). Foreign location choice: Review and extensions. International Journal of Management Reviews, 18(2), 133-159. https://doi.org/10.1111/ijmr.12064 Kogut, B., & Singh, H. (1988). The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 19(3), 411-432. Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. (1999). Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational enterprise. The Academy of Management Review, 24(1), 64 81. https://doi.org/ 10.2307/259037 Krugman, P. (1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 483 499. https://doi.org/10.1086/261763 Lamin, A., & Livanis, G. (2013). Agglomeration, catch-up and the liability of foreignness in emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(6), 579-606. https://doi.org/10.1057/ jibs.2013.14 Lau, C., Tse, D., & Zhou, N. (2002). Institutional forces and organizational culture in China: Effects on change schemas, firm commitment and job satisfaction. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(3), 533-550. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8491030 Lu, J. (2002). Intra-and inter-organizational imitative behavior: Institutional influences on Japanese firms' entry mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(1), 19-37. https://doi.org/ 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8491003 Lu, J., Liu, X., Wright, M., & Filatotchev, I. (2014). International experience and FDI location choices of Chinese firms: the moderating effects of home country government support and host country institutions. Journal of International Business Studies, 45(4), 428 449. https://doi.org/10.1057/ jibs.2013.68 Lundvall, B. (1992). National systems of innovation, London, United Kingdom: Printer press.INMR Lundvall, B. (2007). National innovation systems: Analytical concept and development tool. Industry & 17,4 Innovation, 14(1), 95-119. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662710601130863 Luo, Y., & Tung, R. L. (2007). International expansion of emerging market enterprises: A springboard perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4), 481-498. https://doi.org/10.1057/ palgrave.jibs.8400275 Ma, X., & Delios, A. (2007). A new tale of two cities: Japanese FDIs in Shanghai and Beijing, 1979-2003. 366 International Business Review, 16(2), 207-228. Ma, X., & Delios, A. (2010). Host-country headquarters and an MNE's subsequent within-country diversifications. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(3), 517-525 Ma, X., Delios, A., & Lau, C. (2013). Beijing or Shanghai? The strategic location choice of large MNEs' host-country headquarters in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(9), 953-961. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2013.49 Ma, X., Tong, T. W., & Fitza, M. (2013). How much does subnational region matter to foreign subsidiary performance? Evidence from Fortune Global 500 Corporations' investment in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 44(1), 66-87. Makino, S., Lau, C., & Yeh, R. (2002). Asset-exploitation versus asset-seeking: Implications for location choice of foreign direct investment from newly industrialized economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(3), 403 421. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8491024 Maurer, S., & Zugelder, M. (2000). Trade secret management in high technology: A legal review and research agenda. The Journal of High Technology Management Research, 11(2), 155-174. https:// doi.org/10.1016/S1047-8310(00)00027-4 Mccann, P. (1995). Rethinking the economics of location and agglomeration. Urban Studies, 32(3), 563-577. https://doi.org/10.1080/00420989550012979 Meyer, K. E. (2001). Institutions, transaction costs, and entry mode choice in Eastern Europe. Journal of International Business Studies, 32(2), 357-367. Meyer, K., & Nguyen, H. (2005). Foreign investment strategies and subnational institutions in emerging markets: Evidence from Vietnam. Journal of Management Studies, 42(1), 63-93. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2005.00489.x Meyer, K. E., Ding, Y., Li, J., & Zhang, H. (2014). Overcoming distrust: How state-owned enterprises adapt their foreign entries to institutional pressures abroad. Journal of International Business Studies, 45(8), 1005-1028. Mowery, D., & Oxley, J. (1995). Inward technology transfer and competitiveness: The role of national innovation systems. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), 67-93. https://doi.org/10.1093/ oxfordjournals.cje.a035310 Mudambi, R. (2008). Location, control and innovation in knowledge-intensive industries. Journal of Economic Geography, 8(5), 699-725. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/Ibn024 Mueller, M., Hendriks, G., & Slangen, A. (2017). How the direction of institutional distance influences foreign entry mode choices: An information economics perspective. Distance in international business: Concept, cost and value, Emerald Publishing Limited, Bingley, pp. 271-296. Mueller, S., & Thomas, A. (2001). Culture and entrepreneurial potential: A nine country study of locus of control and innovativeness. Journal of Business Venturing, 16(1), 51-75. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/S0883-9026(99)00039-7 Nelson, R. (1993). National innovation systems: a comparative analysis, Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press. Nguyen, T. V., Le, N. T., & Bryant, S. E. (2013). Sub-national institutions, firm strategies, and firm performance: A multilevel study of private manufacturing firms in Vietnam. Journal of World Business, 48(1), 68-76. North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Pearce, G., & Ayres, S. (2009). Governance in the English regions: the role of the regional development Subnational agencies. Urban Studies, 46(3), 537-557. https://doi.org/10.1177/0042098008100994 location choice Peng, M., Wang, D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). An institution-based view of international business strategy: A focus on emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(5), 920-936. https:// doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400377 Pinto, C. F., Ferreira, M.P., Falaster, C., Fleury, M. T. L., & Fleury, A. (2017). Ownership in cross-border acquisitions and the role of government support. Journal of World Business, 52(4), 533-545 367 Piscitello, L. (2011). Strategy, location, and the conceptual metamorphosis of the MNE. Global Strategy Journal, 1(1-2), 127-131. https://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.14 Porter, M. (1998). Clusters and the new economics of competition. Harvard Business Review, 76(6), 77-90. 10187248. Pouder, R., & John, C. (1996). Hot spots and blind spots: Geographical clusters of firms and innovation. The Academy of Management Review, 21(4), 1192-1225. https://doi.org/10.2307/259168 Ramasamy, B., Yeung, M., & Laforet, S. (2012). China's outward foreign direct investment: Location choice and firm ownership. Journal of World Business, 47(1), 17-25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. jwb.2010.10.016 Rasiah, R. (2017). The role of institutions and linkages in learning and innovation. Institutions and Economies, 3(2), 165-172. Roth, K., & Kostova, T. (2003). Organizational coping with institutional upheaval in transition economies. Journal of World Business, 38(4), 314-330. https://doi.org/

Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

blur-text-image

Get Instant Access with AI-Powered Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image

Step: 3

blur-text-image

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

Entrepreneurship

Authors: Andrew Zacharakis, William D Bygrave

5th Edition

9781119563099

Students also viewed these General Management questions