Answered step by step
Verified Expert Solution
Link Copied!

Question

1 Approved Answer

World folklore and history are replete with examples that involve economics principles. A sizable portion of these concern both military and nonmilitary endeavors that proved

World folklore and history are replete with examples that involve economics principles. A sizable portion of these concern both military and nonmilitary endeavors that proved costly in terms of lives lost. In the past two decades, economic angles to a few of these stories have been described in the literature. These include, but are not limited to, Anderson and Tollison (1991), Goff and Tollison (1987), McClure and Van Cott (1994) and Mixon (1993, 2000)[1]. The last in this list employs a stylized, static monopoly model - developed originally by Ekelund et al. (1989, 1991) to examine the medieval Catholic Church - in order to explore the marketpull aspects of the Salem witch trials episode of 1692. As Mixon (2000, p. 179) points out, the historical evidence concerning the witchcraft episode in Salem suggests that the ministers, including Samuel Parris (the Salem village minister who led the witch trials episode), successfully employed Puritan religious doctrine regarding witchcraft to increase the demand for ministerial services and thus church membership.

Such an economic interpretation of events is perfectly consistent with previous medical explanations concerning the delirium/melancholia of the young, female accusers, such as with the hypothesis concerning ergotism (i.e. bread poisoning) in Mappen (1980). As Mixon (2000, p. 181) suggests, medical hypotheses explain only the physical symptoms of the accusers, while an economic interpretation endeavors to explain the behavior of Reverend Parris, the other ministers, and the institutional church they represented at the time.

A "new interpretation" of events in Salem developed by Carlson (1999) posits that the behavior of the accusers is explained by an outbreak of encephalitis. An adequate epidemiological case is made to describe the physical symptoms/behavior of the young girls (i.e. the "bewitched" accusers). These arguments are supported by the region's geography, given that most of the accusers who suffered physical symptoms (e.g. delirium, etc.) resided in the western half of Salem village, near the Ipswich river - an attractive nesting ground for mosquito populations. Carlson's case is, arguably, more convincing than Mappen's regarding the condition of the young accusers during the episode (i.e. their physical symptoms/behavior). Again, little is done to advance the economic aspects of the events. The present research, unlike the monopoly model analysis of Mixon (2000), builds upon the explanation of Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) by providing an empirical investigation of the (historical) geographic, social and economic patterns of the witch trials in 1692. Such tests reject any proposed randomness (Carlson, 1999, p. xiii) to these spatial patterns that has been the focus of prior research. Finally, the analysis presented here serves as a template for examining other witchhunt events in Europe and Africa (Parrinder, 1970; Willis, 1995).

Factionalism in Salem village as a public choice catalyst: a brief history

In their well-regarded history of events in 1692 Salem, Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) detailed some of the economic and social patterns of accusations of witchcraft. Although the first three people accused of witchcraft were considered "deviants" or "outcasts", a clear dichotomy exists in the accusation pattern beginning in March 1692. Two of the accused in March of that year were church members and wives of prosperous freeholders. In April 1692, 22 individuals were accused, including Phillip English (the wealthiest ship owner in Salem) and George Burroughs (Harvard graduate, who owned a considerable estate in England). By the end of the summer of 1692, the accused included several men with "great estates" in Boston (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, p. 32). These included two sons of the distinguished former Governor, Simon Broadstreet, Nathanial Saltonstall (member of the Governor's Council), and Lady Phips (wife of the current Governor of Massachusetts). As one attorney who prepared the cases against the accused wrote at the end of May 1692, "The afflicted spare no person of what quality so ever" (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, p. 32).

As Boyer and Nissenbaum point out, the accusers did not know most of the people whom they accused of witchcraft. The alleged witches and those who accused them lived on opposite sides of Salem village (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, pp. 335). According to these authors:

Whatever was troubling the girls and those who encouraged them, it was something deeper than the kind of chronic, petty squabbles between near neighbors which seem to have been the root of earlier and far less severe witchcraft episodes in New England." (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, pp. 335).


The political history of the region suggests a public choice interpretation of the pattern of accusations during the episode. As Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974, p. 39) point out, although Salem town was becoming steadily more mercantile, Salem town "had no wish to lose control of the rural hinterland (i.e. the adjacent Salem village) which not only increased her tax revenues, but provided the food which the (Salem) town proper could not supply". As these authors suggest:

The town's concern over the separatist tendencies of her agricultural regions was intensified when several of these regions did, in fact, break away to become independent towns: Wenham in 1643, Manchester in 1645, Marblehead in 1648, and Beverly in 1668. Clearly this trend needed to be checked, and when the Salem (village) farmers showed signs, late in the 1660s, of going in the same direction, the town determined to take a stand" (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, pp. 3940).


The period of conflict between the two locales involved "scores of petitions, resolutions, depositions, and protests" regarding the village's economic, political, and religious independence from the town (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, p. 40). The conflict, however, was more complex than simply town versus village. As Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) detailed, in at least two important respects - quality of land and access to market - the Salem farmers on the east side of the village had a significant advantage over those on the west side. "Modern topographical maps show ... (that) the best lands in the village were the broad, flat meadows of the eastern part ... (and the) eastern side of the village, too, was significantly closer to the network of roads and waterways which gave access to Salem town and her markets ... In both these respects, then, the farmers on this side ... had a crucial edge in supplying the ... town" (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, p. 94). Given the additional fact that the eastern side contained most of the village's other commercial activity, it is evident that the easterners were brought into more regular contact and shared the economic, political and religious interests of the town (Boyer and Nissenbaum, 1974, pp. 948) [2]. Thus, there was an incentive for western villagers to oppose the eastern villagers in a political struggle. We explore (empirically) the relationship between this political factionalism and the pattern of events during the Salem witch trials. Our tests refute any randomness to the pattern of indictments and death.

Public choice and the allocation of death: empirical evidence

Table I presents data from Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974, pp. 345) regarding geographic patterns of prosecution and defense during the witch trials phenomenon[3]. Based on data analysis provided by Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) suggesting roughly equal populations at either ends of Salem village (i.e. the east and west), the exhibited patterns of accusations or support for the judicial prosecution of the "witches" can be tested against a random pattern. These tests synthesize the public choice explanation of events at that time, as put forth by Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) and, to a lesser degree, by Mixon (2000)[4].

The first percentages detailed in Table I suggest that the vast majority of the accused (who lived within the bounds of Salem village) resided in the eastern section of the village (i.e. from those areas less supportive of Reverend Parris and more amenable to social, political and economic alignment with Salem town). This figure - 86 percent - is statistically different from a random expectation (i.e. roughly 50 percent) at the 95 percent level of confidence. The second entry in Table I points out that the "accusers" (i.e. those supporting/assisting in the prosecution of the Salem "witches" through testimony and other means) resided overwhelmingly in the western part of the village. Once again, the exhibited pattern is statistically different from a random pattern (at the 99 percent level of confidence). The final entry in Table I indicates that the percent of Salem village citizens in opposition to, or skeptical of, the entire witchcraft episode at the time resided primarily in the eastern part of the village. A random expectation regarding the geography of opposition or skepticism is rejected, at the 99 percent confidence level, by the actual or exhibited percentage.

The findings of Table I are consistent with epidemiological theories, such as that of Carlson (1999), given that they suggest that the "accusers" were statistically more likely to reside in the west versus a random location pattern. This supports the thesis of encephalitis, given the location of the Ipswich river. However, the fact that "accusers" from the west were statistically more likely to indict, as "witches", eastern villagers (compared to a random pattern of indictments) during the witch trials episode supports the notion that the cycle of events was politicized by Parris and the other ministers involved in the trials. The evidence is consistent with the theory that Parris and the ministers directed their indictments and death sentences at their eastern opposition. East Salem farmers were more politically aligned with Salem town, and the statistical tests support the notion that the ministers used the trials strategically to solidify the position of the institutional church they represented at the time. As Mixon (2000, p. 182) states, the ministers used the events of 1692 to initiate "... a crusade against many of Salem's citizens". As we suggest, these "citizens" were statistically most likely to be eastern village farmers or mercantilists, who politically opposed Parris and the western villagers.

Table II presents additional data from Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974, pp. 824) that relate to other dimensions of factional conflict. Among the 35 households refusing to support the tax petition to provide ministerial remuneration to Reverend Parris in 16951696, tax documents suggest that the distribution of income/wealth was approximately uniform (i.e. the figures - 43, 34 and 23 percent - are not individually statistically different from 33 percent). Among propetition villagers, a distinct economic pattern emerges. The percent of support drawn from villagers paying under 10 shillings in taxes exceeds the expectation of uniformity (i.e. 33 percent) at the 99 percent confidence level, while the percent of support coming from those paying over 20 shillings in taxes falls short of uniformity (i.e. 33 percent) at the 99 percent confidence level.

Additionally, the lower income (<10 shillings) villagers exhibited a statistically greater representation among the proParris (i.e. propetition) faction than the antiParris faction (i.e. 61 percent is greater than 43 percent at the 90 percent confidence level). Similarly, the upper income (>20 shillings) villagers exhibited a statistically greater representation among the antiParris faction than the proParris faction (at the 95 percent confidence level)[5]. These tests suggest that the income distributions for pro and antiParris sentiment in the village were statistically different, and they also support the geographical pattern described earlier, given that most of the wealth of Salem village resided on its eastern side. The complex public intertwining of geography and economics, as well as religion, in Salem village in 1692 and later, works to support a political interpretation of events. As Mixon (2000, p. 182) concluded, the "... Salem witchcraft episode shows how relatively easy it was in colonial North America for ministers to interpret questionable actions as witchcraft ... In this case, the ... consequence of doctrinal innovation meant that, between June 10 and September 22 of 1692, 19 men and women along with two dogs were hanged to death as witches, and one man was pressed to death for refusing to plead to the indictment of witchcraft". The present note synthesizes and supports public choice hypotheses by statistically refuting the proposition that the pattern of events in 1692 Salem was random (Carlson, 1999).

Concluding comments

In this paper, we have attempted to advance public choice aspects of the Salem witch trials. Specifically, we build upon Boyer and Nissenbaum (1974) by undertaking some empirical testing of the geographical, social, and economic patterns of prosecution and defense in the 1692 Salem witch trials. Our analysis suggests that the "accusers" were statistically more likely to reside in the western portion of Salem village (in 1692) than a random pattern would suggest. However, the fact that "accusers" from the west were statistically more likely to indict, as "witches", eastern villagers (compared to a random pattern of indictments) supports the notion that the cycle of events was politicized by Reverend Parris and the other ministers involved in the trials. The ministers drew support from, and thus supported, western villagers in their struggles versus the eastern villagers and Salem town over economic and religious selfdetermination. In one sense, the entire episode is analogous to a modernday geographic annexation battle gone awry, wherein 19 men and women were hanged to death as witches, and one man was pressed to death for refusing to plead to the indictment of witchcraft. Thus, our tests add to the public choice literature by refuting the proposed randomness of the spatial patterns.



Step by Step Solution

There are 3 Steps involved in it

Step: 1

ANSWER The excerpt delves into the Salem witch trials of 1692 examining them through an economic lens particularly utilizing the framework of public c... blur-text-image

Get Instant Access to Expert-Tailored Solutions

See step-by-step solutions with expert insights and AI powered tools for academic success

Step: 2

blur-text-image

Step: 3

blur-text-image

Ace Your Homework with AI

Get the answers you need in no time with our AI-driven, step-by-step assistance

Get Started

Recommended Textbook for

An Introduction To Statistical Methods And Data Analysis

Authors: R. Lyman Ott, Micheal T. Longnecker

7th Edition

1305269470, 978-1305465527, 1305465520, 978-1305269477

More Books

Students also viewed these Economics questions